Siga este link para ver outros tipos de publicações sobre o tema: Choice correspondences.

Artigos de revistas sobre o tema "Choice correspondences"

Crie uma referência precisa em APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, e outros estilos

Selecione um tipo de fonte:

Veja os 50 melhores artigos de revistas para estudos sobre o assunto "Choice correspondences".

Ao lado de cada fonte na lista de referências, há um botão "Adicionar à bibliografia". Clique e geraremos automaticamente a citação bibliográfica do trabalho escolhido no estilo de citação de que você precisa: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

Você também pode baixar o texto completo da publicação científica em formato .pdf e ler o resumo do trabalho online se estiver presente nos metadados.

Veja os artigos de revistas das mais diversas áreas científicas e compile uma bibliografia correta.

1

Campbell, Donald E., e Jerry S. Kelly. "Arrovian Social Choice Correspondences". International Economic Review 37, n.º 4 (novembro de 1996): 803. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2527312.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
2

Laslier, Jean-François. "Rank-based choice correspondences". Economics Letters 52, n.º 3 (setembro de 1996): 279–86. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s0165-1765(96)00877-4.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
3

Lombardi, Michele. "Reason-based choice correspondences". Mathematical Social Sciences 57, n.º 1 (janeiro de 2009): 58–66. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2008.07.001.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
4

Campbell, Donald E., e Jerry S. Kelly. "Independent social choice correspondences". Theory and Decision 41, n.º 1 (julho de 1996): 1–11. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/bf00134113.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
5

Costa, Matheus, Paulo Henrique Ramos e Gil Riella. "Single-crossing choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 54, n.º 1 (23 de agosto de 2019): 69–86. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-019-01212-7.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
6

Stefanescu, Anton. "Impossibility results for choice correspondences". Mathematical Social Sciences 33, n.º 2 (abril de 1997): 129–48. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s0165-4896(96)00829-3.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
7

Kelly, Jerry S., e Shaofang Qi. "Balancedness of social choice correspondences". Mathematical Social Sciences 102 (novembro de 2019): 59–67. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2019.08.003.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
8

Barberà, Salvador, Bhaskar Dutta e Arunava Sen. "Strategy-proof Social Choice Correspondences". Journal of Economic Theory 101, n.º 2 (dezembro de 2001): 374–94. http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jeth.2000.2782.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
9

Klaus, Bettina, e Ton Storcken. "Choice correspondences for public goods". Social Choice and Welfare 19, n.º 1 (1 de janeiro de 2002): 127–54. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s355-002-8329-7.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
10

Dutta, Bhaskar, e Jean-Francois Laslier. "Comparison functions and choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 16, n.º 4 (2 de setembro de 1999): 513–32. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s003550050158.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
11

Borm, Peter, René van den Brink, René Levı́nský e Marco Slikker. "On two new social choice correspondences". Mathematical Social Sciences 47, n.º 1 (janeiro de 2004): 51–68. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s0165-4896(03)00070-2.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
12

Bubboloni, Daniela, e Michele Gori. "Resolute refinements of social choice correspondences". Mathematical Social Sciences 84 (novembro de 2016): 37–49. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2016.08.007.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
13

Denicolò, Vincenzo. "Independent social choice correspondences are dictatorial". Economics Letters 19, n.º 1 (janeiro de 1985): 9–12. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-1765(85)90092-8.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
14

Stoye, Jörg. "Axioms for minimax regret choice correspondences". Journal of Economic Theory 146, n.º 6 (novembro de 2011): 2226–51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2011.10.004.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
15

Özyurt, Selçuk, e M. Remzi Sanver. "Strategy-proof resolute social choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 30, n.º 1 (20 de março de 2007): 89–101. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-007-0223-6.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
16

Sato, Shin. "On strategy-proof social choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 31, n.º 2 (8 de dezembro de 2007): 331–43. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-007-0285-5.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
17

Sato, Shin. "On strategy-proof social choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 32, n.º 2 (28 de fevereiro de 2008): 335–36. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-008-0304-1.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
18

Peris, Josep E., e Begoña Subiza. "Condorcet choice correspondences for weak tournaments". Social Choice and Welfare 16, n.º 2 (3 de fevereiro de 1999): 217–31. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s003550050141.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
19

Peleg, Bezalel, Hans Peters e Ton Storcken. "Constitutional implementation of social choice correspondences". International Journal of Game Theory 33, n.º 3 (setembro de 2005): 381–96. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s001820400179.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
20

Jain, Ritesh. "Rationalizable implementation of social choice correspondences". Games and Economic Behavior 127 (maio de 2021): 47–66. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2021.02.004.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
21

Lahiri, Somdeb. "The No-Spoiler Condition for Choice Correspondences". Multiple Criteria Decision Making 14 (2019): 60–74. http://dx.doi.org/10.22367/mcdm.2019.14.04.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
22

Kutlu, Levent. "Intersection of Nash implementable social choice correspondences". Mathematical Social Sciences 55, n.º 2 (março de 2008): 255–57. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2007.09.002.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
23

Yamato, Takehiko. "On nash implementation of social choice correspondences". Games and Economic Behavior 4, n.º 3 (julho de 1992): 484–92. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0899-8256(92)90051-s.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
24

Fuchs-Seliger, Susanne. "Order extensions, budget correspondences, and rational choice". Theory and Decision 72, n.º 4 (16 de setembro de 2011): 431–44. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11238-011-9278-z.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
25

Rodríguez-Álvarez, Carmelo. "On the manipulation of social choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 29, n.º 2 (19 de dezembro de 2006): 175–99. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-006-0212-1.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
26

Ertemel, Sinan, Levent Kutlu e M. Remzi Sanver. "Voting games of resolute social choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 45, n.º 1 (31 de janeiro de 2015): 187–201. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-015-0872-9.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
27

Sánchez, M. Carmen, e Josep E. Peris. "Veto in fixed agenda social choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 16, n.º 1 (1 de janeiro de 1999): 81–97. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s003550050132.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
28

Laffond, Gilbert, Jean François Laslier e Michel Le Breton. "Condorcet choice correspondences: A set-theoretical comparison". Mathematical Social Sciences 30, n.º 1 (agosto de 1995): 23–35. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-4896(94)00778-7.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
29

Laffond, G., J. F. Laslier e M. Le Breton. "Condorcet choice correspondences: A set-theoretical comparison". Mathematical Social Sciences 31, n.º 1 (fevereiro de 1996): 59. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-4896(96)88687-2.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
30

Denicolò, Vincenzo. "Fixed Agenda Social Choice Theory: Correspondence and Impossibility Theorems for Social Choice Correspondences and Social Decision Functions". Journal of Economic Theory 59, n.º 2 (abril de 1993): 324–32. http://dx.doi.org/10.1006/jeth.1993.1021.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
31

Tanaka, Yasuhito. "Garchy for Social Choice Correspondences and Strategy-Proofness". Theory and Decision 55, n.º 3 (novembro de 2003): 273–87. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/b:theo.0000044593.23976.07.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
32

Rodríguez-Álvarez, Carmelo. "On strategy-proof social choice correspondences: a comment". Social Choice and Welfare 32, n.º 1 (2 de abril de 2008): 29–35. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-008-0309-9.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
33

Fristrup, Peter, e Hans Keiding. "Strongly implementable social choice correspondences and the supernucleus". Social Choice and Welfare 18, n.º 2 (19 de abril de 2001): 213–26. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s003550100100.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
34

Tamaki, Mitsushi. "Urn sampling distributions giving alternate correspondences between two optimal stopping problems". Advances in Applied Probability 48, n.º 3 (setembro de 2016): 726–43. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/apr.2016.25.

Texto completo da fonte
Resumo:
Abstract The best-choice problem and the duration problem, known as versions of the secretary problem, are concerned with choosing an object from those that appear sequentially. Let (B,p) denote the best-choice problem and (D,p) the duration problem when the total number N of objects is a bounded random variable with prior p=(p1, p2,...,pn) for a known upper bound n. Gnedin (2005) discovered the correspondence relation between these two quite different optimal stopping problems. That is, for any given prior p, there exists another prior q such that (D,p) is equivalent to (B,q). In this paper, motivated by his discovery, we attempt to find the alternate correspondence {p(m),m≥0}, i.e. an infinite sequence of priors such that (D,p(m-1)) is equivalent to (B,p(m)) for all m≥1, starting with p(0)=(0,...,0,1). To be more precise, the duration problem is distinguished into (D1,p) or (D2,p), referred to as model 1 or model 2, depending on whether the planning horizon is N or n. The aforementioned problem is model 1. For model 2 as well, we can find the similar alternate correspondence {p[m],m≥ 0}. We treat both the no-information model and the full-information model and examine the limiting behaviors of their optimal rules and optimal values related to the alternate correspondences as n→∞. A generalization of the no-information model is given. It is worth mentioning that the alternate correspondences for model 1 and model 2 are respectively related to the urn sampling models without replacement and with replacement.
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
35

Klaus, Bettina, e Panos Protopapas. "On strategy-proofness and single-peakedness: median-voting over intervals". International Journal of Game Theory 49, n.º 4 (17 de novembro de 2020): 1059–80. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00182-020-00728-y.

Texto completo da fonte
Resumo:
AbstractWe study correspondences that choose an interval of alternatives when agents have single-peaked preferences over locations and ordinally extend their preferences over intervals. We extend the main results of Moulin (Public Choice 35:437–455, 1980) to our setting and show that the results of Ching (Soc Choice Welf 26:473–490, 1997) cannot always be similarly extended. First, strategy-proofness and peaks-onliness characterize the class of generalized median correspondences (Theorem 1). Second, this result neither holds on the domain of symmetric and single-peaked preferences, nor can in this result min/max continuity substitute peaks-onliness (see counter-Example 3). Third, strategy-proofness and voter-sovereignty characterize the class of efficient generalized median correspondences (Theorem 2).
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
36

Alemante, Fasil, Donald E. Campbell e Jerry S. Kelly. "Characterizing the resolute part of monotonic social choice correspondences". Economic Theory 62, n.º 4 (12 de novembro de 2015): 765–83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00199-015-0930-7.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
37

Takayama, Shino, e Akira Yokotani. "Social choice correspondences with infinitely many agents: serial dictatorship". Social Choice and Welfare 48, n.º 3 (16 de janeiro de 2017): 573–98. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1025-0.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
38

GOSWAMI, USHA, JOHANNES C. ZIEGLER, LOUISE DALTON e WOLFGANG SCHNEIDER. "Nonword reading across orthographies: How flexible is the choice of reading units?" Applied Psycholinguistics 24, n.º 2 (junho de 2003): 235–47. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s0142716403000134.

Texto completo da fonte
Resumo:
It was predicted that children learning to read inconsistent orthographies (e.g., English) should show considerable flexibility in making use of spelling–sound correspondences at different unit sizes whereas children learning to read consistent orthographies (e.g., German) should mainly employ small-size grapheme–phoneme strategies. This hypothesis was tested in a cross-language blocking experiment using nonwords that could only be read using small-size grapheme–phoneme correspondences (small-unit nonwords) and phonologically identical nonwords that could be decoded using larger correspondences (large-unit nonwords). These small-unit and large-unit nonwords were either presented mixed together in the same lists or blocked by unit size. It was found that English children, but not German children, showed blocking effects (better performance when items were blocked by nonword type than in mixed lists). This suggests that in mixed lists, English readers have to switch back and forth between small-unit and large-unit processing, resulting in switching costs. These results are interpreted in terms of differences concerning the grain size of the phonological recoding mechanisms developed by English and German children.
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
39

Yao, Haixiang, e Jianxin Yi. "A characterization of dictatorial social choice correspondences with continuous preferences". Mathematical Social Sciences 55, n.º 3 (maio de 2008): 299–304. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2007.09.003.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
40

Umezawa, Masashi. "Coalitionally strategy-proof social choice correspondences and the Pareto rule". Social Choice and Welfare 33, n.º 1 (10 de dezembro de 2008): 151–58. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-008-0351-7.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
41

McKelvey, R. D. "Game forms for Nash implementation of general social choice correspondences". Social Choice and Welfare 6, n.º 2 (abril de 1989): 139–56. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/bf00303168.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
42

Klein, Harriet B., Susan H. Lederer e Emma E. Cortese. "Children’s Knowledge of Auditory/Articulatory Correspondences". Journal of Speech, Language, and Hearing Research 34, n.º 3 (junho de 1991): 559–64. http://dx.doi.org/10.1044/jshr.3403.559.

Texto completo da fonte
Resumo:
Forty-five normally developing children, 15 within each group of mean ages 5, 6, and 7, participated in a metaphonologic study examining the knowledge of auditory/articulatory correspondences Tasks included (a) a nonverbal identification of correspondences by selecting the appropriate side of a split video screen display, and (b) a verbal explanation of the cues used to motivate this choice. With development, there were significant increases in numbers of correct responses on the nonverbal task and corresponding changes in relative proportions of verbal explanation types. No significant relationship between level of performance on metaphonologic tasks and phoneme production skill was found.
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
43

Carey, A., M. Farber e V. Mathai. "Correspondences, von Neumann Algebras and Holomorphic L2 Torsion". Canadian Journal of Mathematics 52, n.º 4 (1 de agosto de 2000): 695–736. http://dx.doi.org/10.4153/cjm-2000-030-7.

Texto completo da fonte
Resumo:
AbstractGiven a holomorphic Hilbertian bundle on a compact complex manifold, we introduce the notion of holomorphic L2 torsion, which lies in the determinant line of the twisted L2 Dolbeault cohomology and represents a volume element there. Here we utilise the theory of determinant lines of Hilbertian modules over finite von Neumann algebras as developed in [CFM]. This specialises to the Ray-Singer-Quillen holomorphic torsion in the finite dimensional case. We compute ametric variation formula for the holomorphic L2 torsion, which shows that it is not in general independent of the choice of Hermitian metrics on the complex manifold and on the holomorphic Hilbertian bundle, which are needed to define it. We therefore initiate the theory of correspondences of determinant lines, that enables us to define a relative holomorphic L2 torsion for a pair of flat Hilbertian bundles, which we prove is independent of the choice of Hermitian metrics on the complex manifold and on the flat Hilbertian bundles.
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
44

Campbell, Donald E., e Jerry S. Kelly. "The finer structure of resolute, neutral, and anonymous social choice correspondences". Economics Letters 132 (julho de 2015): 109–11. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2015.04.026.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
45

Espunya, Anna. "Contrastive and translational issues in rendering the English progressive form into Spanish and Catalan: an informant-based study". Meta 46, n.º 3 (2 de outubro de 2002): 535–51. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/002710ar.

Texto completo da fonte
Resumo:
Abstract This is a study on the formal correspondences for the English progressive in translations from English to Spanish and Catalan, with a special focus on the choice between simple and progressive forms. Its methodological approach includes the participation of informants both as translators and as evaluators of published translations. The paper discusses both the language-internal and task-related factors that play a role in the choice of verb forms.
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
46

Crisinel, Anne-Sylvie, e Charles Spence. "Crossmodal correspondences between chemosensory stimuli and musical notes". Seeing and Perceiving 25 (2012): 72. http://dx.doi.org/10.1163/187847612x646938.

Texto completo da fonte
Resumo:
We report a series of experiments investigating crossmodal correspondences between various food-related stimuli (water-based solutions, milk-based flavoured solutions, crisps, chocolate and odours) and sounds varying in pitch and played by four different types of musical instruments. Participants tasted or smelled stimuli before matching them to a musical note. Our results demonstrate that participants preferentially match certain stimuli to specific pitches and instrument types. Through participants’ ratings of the stimuli along a number of dimensions (e.g., pleasantness, complexity, familiarity or sweetness), we explore the psychological dimensions involved in these crossmodal correspondences, using principal components analysis (PCA). While pleasantness seems to play an important role in the choice of instrument associated with chemosensory stimuli, the pitch seems to also depend on the quality of the taste (bitter, salty, sour or sweet). The level at which such crossmodal correspondences might occur, as well as the potential applications of such results, will be discussed.
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
47

Tchantcho, Bertrand, e Lawrence Diffo Lambo. "A characterization of social choice correspondences that implement the core of simple games". Economic Theory 37, n.º 3 (14 de dezembro de 2007): 533–42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00199-007-0317-5.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
48

Thomson, William. "A study of choice correspondences in economies with a variable number of agents". Journal of Economic Theory 46, n.º 2 (dezembro de 1988): 237–54. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(88)90130-5.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
49

Barbera, Salvador, Bhaskar Dutta e Arunava Sen. "Corrigendum to “Strategy-proof social choice correspondences” [J. Econ. Theory 101 (2001) 374–394]". Journal of Economic Theory 120, n.º 2 (fevereiro de 2005): 275. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jet.2004.02.005.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
50

Sato, Shin. "A fundamental structure of strategy-proof social choice correspondences with restricted preferences over alternatives". Social Choice and Welfare 42, n.º 4 (27 de julho de 2013): 831–51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-013-0755-x.

Texto completo da fonte
Estilos ABNT, Harvard, Vancouver, APA, etc.
Oferecemos descontos em todos os planos premium para autores cujas obras estão incluídas em seleções literárias temáticas. Contate-nos para obter um código promocional único!

Vá para a bibliografia