To see the other types of publications on this topic, follow the link: Condorcet paradox.

Journal articles on the topic 'Condorcet paradox'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the top 33 journal articles for your research on the topic 'Condorcet paradox.'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Browse journal articles on a wide variety of disciplines and organise your bibliography correctly.

1

Herings, P. Jean-Jacques, and Harold Houba. "The Condorcet paradox revisited." Social Choice and Welfare 47, no. 1 (2016): 141–86. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-016-0950-7.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Laffond, Gilbert, and Jean Lainé. "Condorcet choice and the Ostrogorski paradox." Social Choice and Welfare 32, no. 2 (2008): 317–33. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00355-008-0325-9.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Pérez, Joaquín, José L. Jimeno, and Estefanía García. "No Show Paradox in Condorcet k-voting Procedures." Group Decision and Negotiation 21, no. 3 (2010): 291–303. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10726-010-9191-9.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Jones, Bradford, Benjamin Radcliff, Charles Taber, and Richard Timpone. "Condorcet Winners and the Paradox of Voting: Probability Calculations for Weak Preference Orders." American Political Science Review 89, no. 1 (1995): 137–44. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2083080.

Full text
Abstract:
That individual preferences may he aggregated into a meaningful collective decision using the Condorcet criterion of majority choice is one of the central tenets of democracy. But that individual preferences may not yield majority winners is one of the classic findings of the social choice literature. Given this problem, social choice theorists have attempted to estimate the probability of Condorcet winners, given certain empirical or theoretical conditions. We shall estimate the probabilities of Condorcet winners and intransitive aggregate orders for various numbers of individuals with strong
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Kalai, Gil. "A Fourier-theoretic perspective on the Condorcet paradox and Arrow's theorem." Advances in Applied Mathematics 29, no. 3 (2002): 412–26. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s0196-8858(02)00023-4.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Weber, James S. "An elementary proof of the conditions for a generalized Condorcet paradox." Public Choice 77, no. 2 (1993): 415–19. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/bf01047879.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Pérez, Joaquín, José L. Jimeno, and Estefanía García. "No Show Paradox and the Golden Number in Generalized Condorcet Voting Methods." Group Decision and Negotiation 24, no. 3 (2014): 497–513. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10726-014-9416-4.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Zhan, Ping. "A simple construction of complete single-peaked domains by recursive tiling." Mathematical Methods of Operations Research 90, no. 3 (2019): 477–88. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00186-019-00685-7.

Full text
Abstract:
Abstract Single-peakedness was introduced by Black (J Political Econ 56:23–34, 1948) as a sufficient condition to overcome Condorcet paradox. Since then it has been attracting interest from researchers in various fields. In this paper, we propose a simple recursive procedure of constructing complete single-peaked domains of tiling type explicitly for any finite alternative sets, by combining two results published in recent years, and some observations of known results and examples by the author. The underlying basic structure of tiling type and properties of single-peaked domains provided here
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Rouncefield, Mary, and David Green. "Condorcet's Paradox." Teaching Statistics 11, no. 2 (1989): 46–49. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9639.1989.tb00050.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Couppey-Soubeyran, Jézabel. "Le paradoxe de Condorcet." Alternatives Économiques N° 323, no. 4 (2013): 72. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/ae.323.0072.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
11

Qudrat-I Elahi, Khandakar. "A difficulty in Arrow’s impossibility theorem." International Journal of Social Economics 44, no. 12 (2017): 1609–21. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/ijse-02-2016-0065.

Full text
Abstract:
Purpose The purpose of this paper is twofold. First, it evaluates the impossibility proposition, called the “Arrow impossibility theorem” (AIT), which is widely attributed to Arrow’s social choice theory. This theorem denies the possibility of arriving at any collective majority resolution in any group voting system if the social choice function must satisfy “certain natural conditions”. Second, it intends to show the reasons behind the proliferation of this impossibility impression. Design/methodology/approach Theoretical and philosophical. Findings Arrow’s mathematical model does not seem to
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
12

Trujillo, Timothy. "Condorcet’s Paradox and Ultrafilters." American Mathematical Monthly 127, no. 2 (2020): 169–74. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00029890.2020.1680200.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
13

Gillard, Lucien. "Condorcet, deux autres paradoxes ?" Annales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales 51, no. 1 (1996): 201–14. http://dx.doi.org/10.3406/ahess.1996.410840.

Full text
Abstract:
La combinaison de systèmes de préférences individuelles peut aboutir globalement à choisir une solution qui ne satisfasse personne. C'est à propos des fonctions de préférences collectives existant à un moment donné que Condorcet démontre son célèbre paradoxe. Il semble que son raisonnement puisse être transposé à la formation dans le temps des systèmes de préférences d'un individu. Confronté à des situations changeantes, un individu élabore au cours de son existence des systèmes multiples de préférences, qui rendent la notion même d'individu paradoxale.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
14

Lepelley, Dominique, and Mathieu Martin. "Condorcet's paradox for weak preference orderings." European Journal of Political Economy 17, no. 1 (2001): 163–77. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s0176-2680(00)00034-3.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
15

Piedra Aguilera, Marco, José Vera Reino, Ana Albornoz, and Camila Palacios. "Condiciones políticas existentes para la fijación de tarifas de agua potable. Análisis desde la paradoja de CONDORCET." Bolentín de Coyuntura 1, no. 22 (2019): 16. http://dx.doi.org/10.31164/bcoyu.22.2019.719.

Full text
Abstract:
El artículo estudia la Paradoja de Condorcet aplicada al funcionamiento del Cabildo Cantonal de Cuenca – Ecuador. La votación realizada al interior de un espacio político obedece a la regla de mayorías aún cuando su decisión involucre el normal desenvolvimiento organizacional. Los hallazgos determinan que por varios años las tarifas de agua potable no fueron modificadas pese a que ETAPA- EP presentaba necesidades de dinero y veía comprometida su operación. Se reconoce la Paradoja de Condorcet cuando las preferencias de los votantes son cíclicas aún a pesar de que la preferencia individual sea
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
16

Peters, Dominik. "Condorcet's Principle and the Preference Reversal Paradox." Electronic Proceedings in Theoretical Computer Science 251 (July 25, 2017): 455–69. http://dx.doi.org/10.4204/eptcs.251.34.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
17

Gehrlein, William V., and Dominique Lepelley. "Condorcet's paradox under the maximal culture condition." Economics Letters 55, no. 1 (1997): 85–89. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s0165-1765(97)00046-3.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
18

Van Deemen, Adrian. "On the empirical relevance of Condorcet’s paradox." Public Choice 158, no. 3-4 (2013): 311–30. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0133-3.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
19

Moulin, Hervé. "Condorcet's principle implies the no show paradox." Journal of Economic Theory 45, no. 1 (1988): 53–64. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(88)90253-0.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
20

Truchon, Michel. "La démocratie : oui, mais laquelle?" L'Actualité économique 75, no. 1-2-3 (2009): 189–214. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/602289ar.

Full text
Abstract:
RÉSUMÉ Cet article illustre les difficultés inhérentes au processus démocratique à partir des résultats d’une consultation tenue à l’Université Laval, dans le cadre de la nomination d’un doyen. Lors de ce scrutin, les votants devaient en principe ordonner tous les candidats, au nombre de quatre. La compilation des résultats s’avérait donc un exercice d’agrégation des ordres (préférences) individuels en ordre (préférence) collectif. L’article emprunte abondamment à la littérature sur la théorie des choix sociaux et constitue en quelque sorte un survol partiel de cette dernière. Il montre d’abor
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
21

Epstein, Isaac. "O paradoxo de Condorcet e a crise da democracia representativa." Estudos Avançados 11, no. 30 (1997): 273–91. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/s0103-40141997000200017.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
22

Tangian, A. S. "Unlikelihood of Condorcet's paradox in a large society." Social Choice and Welfare 17, no. 2 (2000): 337–65. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s003550050024.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
23

Mauerberg Junior, Arnaldo, and Eduardo Strachman. "A regra da maioria como agregação de preferências: questões e respostas." Nova Economia 24, no. 2 (2014): 297–316. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/0103-6351/1831.

Full text
Abstract:
Ancorado na abordagem racionalista, mas na impossibilidade da regra consensual e buscando apresentar as características da regra da maioria e alguns de seus problemas, como o paradoxo de Condorcet, e soluções a esses problemas, como o logrolling, este artigo se propõe a revisar e sintetizar a teoria a respeito, baseado nas principais contribuições ao tema. O estudo se justifica porque, como processo de agregação de preferências, a regra da maioria se destaca para usos eleitorais e de processos políticos internos, em um elevado número de nações.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
24

Gehrlein, William V., Dominique Lepelley, and Issofa Moyouwou. "Voters’ preference diversity, concepts of agreement and Condorcet’s paradox." Quality & Quantity 49, no. 6 (2014): 2345–68. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11135-014-0117-5.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
25

Stodder, James. "Strategic Voting and Coalitions: Condorcet’s Paradox and Ben-Gurion’s Tri-lemma." International Review of Economics Education 4, no. 2 (2005): 58–72. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s1477-3880(15)30131-6.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
26

Gano, Mamadou Kabirou. "L’impensé d’un humanisme, l’autre paradoxe de Condorcet. Considérations autour des Réflexions sur l’esclavage des Nègres." Topique 137, no. 4 (2016): 19. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/top.137.0019.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
27

Boussard, Jean-Marc. "« Du paradoxe de Condorcet à la gestion descommons : Mode de décision et appropriation des rentes »." Revue de l’organisation responsable 7, no. 2 (2012): 46. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/ror.072.0046.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
28

Simpson, William A. "Why search committees must be wary of ex-cavalry officers, Condorcet's paradox, and dictators." Research in Higher Education 29, no. 2 (1988): 149–59. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/bf00992283.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
29

Milojevic, Miljana. "Rationality and deliberative democracy." Theoria, Beograd 53, no. 3 (2010): 71–88. http://dx.doi.org/10.2298/theo1003071m.

Full text
Abstract:
In this paper I will give a short description of deliberative democracy, its advantages over the aggregative model of democracy and its strategies for overcoming the obstacles which the social choice theory puts before the defenders of democracy. I will continue with the argument that the aim of deliberative democracy should not be reaching the consensus or unanimity, but obtaining preference single-peakedness. For, there is a practical impossibility of consensus reaching and the single-peakedness criterion is sufficient for prevention against the 'paradoxes of democracy'. Through the analysis
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
30

Herings, P. Jean-Jacques, and Harold E. D. Houba. "The Condorcet Paradox Revisited." SSRN Electronic Journal, 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1561723.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
31

Herings, P. Jean-Jacques, and Harold Houba. "The Condorcet Paradox Revisited." SSRN Electronic Journal, 2013. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2265943.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
32

Guerra-Pujol, Enrique. "Condorcet's Paradox in Puerto Rico (La paradoja de Condorcet y el caso de Puerto Rico)." SSRN Electronic Journal, 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2817959.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
33

Sebagh, Thierry, and Laurence Lepoder. "Searching for Compatibility between the Jury Theorem and Condorcet's Paradox." SSRN Electronic Journal, 2009. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1331863.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!