Academic literature on the topic 'Divisible and indivisible obligations'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the lists of relevant articles, books, theses, conference reports, and other scholarly sources on the topic 'Divisible and indivisible obligations.'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Journal articles on the topic "Divisible and indivisible obligations"

1

Petrov, V. "Joint and several liability and separate liability of the heirs for hereditable obligations – short comparative and historical overview." Fundamental and applied researches in practice of leading scientific schools 28, no. 4 (September 1, 2018): 114–16. http://dx.doi.org/10.33531/farplss.2018.4.21.

Full text
Abstract:
The article researches the different approaches for regulation of the liability of the heirs for hereditable obligations. Historical and comparative researches were made. The European legislations can be divided in two big groups. The legislations form the first group set a separate liability of the heirs - each one of them owes only a part of the debt equal to his share of the estate. The legislations of France, Ukraine, Bulgaria, etc. are included in this group. The legislations from the second group govern joint and several liability for the heirs. A creditor of the estate has a right to demand an enforcement of the whole size of hereditable obligation from one of the heirs and this enforcement releases all of the heirs from their liability. This group includes the civil legislations of German, Switzerland, Spain, Russian federation, Macedonia, etc. The author position is that the separate liability is more proper for regulation of the heir’s liability for hereditable debts. Historical, comparative and theleological methods are used for proof of this thesis. The historical development of this liability from Roman private law is traced and researched. A short overview of the aims of each one of the two kinds of liability is made in the article. The joint and several liability protects only the interest of the creditors of the estate. It is considered in the doctrine as a debt security. The separate liability protects the interest not only of the creditors, but of the heirs too. But only the liability for divisible obligations is separate. The liability for indivisible obligations is joint and liability. The separate liability can’t be applicable for them because of the specific of this kind of obligations.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Arnoult, Julien. "Indivisible territory and divisible cabinets: Introduction." Tocqueville Review/La revue Tocqueville 35, no. 2 (2014): 7–10. http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/toc.2014.0020.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

McNeill, William H. "Review Article: Our World: Divisible or Indivisible?" Journal of Contemporary History 37, no. 3 (July 2002): 489–95. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/00220094020370031001.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Levy, Omer, Rann Smorodinsky, and Moshe Tennenholtz. "Undivide and Conquer: On Selling a Divisible and Homogeneous Good." B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 15, no. 1 (January 1, 2015): 1–23. http://dx.doi.org/10.1515/bejte-2014-0002.

Full text
Abstract:
AbstractWith the prevalence of cloud computing emerges the challenges of pricing cloud computing services. There are various characteristics of cloud computing which make the problem unique. We study an abstract model which focuses on one such aspect – the sale of a homogeneous and fully divisible good. We cast onto our model the idea of bundling, studied within the context of monopolist pricing of indivisible goods. We demonstrate how selling a divisible good as an indivisible one may increase seller revenues and characterize when this phenomenon occurs, and the corresponding gain factors.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Bei, Xiaohui, Zihao Li, Jinyan Liu, Shengxin Liu, and Xinhang Lu. "Fair Division of Mixed Divisible and Indivisible Goods." Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence 34, no. 02 (April 3, 2020): 1814–21. http://dx.doi.org/10.1609/aaai.v34i02.5548.

Full text
Abstract:
We study the problem of fair division when the resources contain both divisible and indivisible goods. Classic fairness notions such as envy-freeness (EF) and envy-freeness up to one good (EF1) cannot be directly applied to the mixed goods setting. In this work, we propose a new fairness notion envy-freeness for mixed goods (EFM), which is a direct generalization of both EF and EF1 to the mixed goods setting. We prove that an EFM allocation always exists for any number of agents. We also propose efficient algorithms to compute an EFM allocation for two agents and for n agents with piecewise linear valuations over the divisible goods. Finally, we relax the envy-free requirement, instead asking for ϵ-envy-freeness for mixed goods (ϵ-EFM), and present an algorithm that finds an ϵ-EFM allocation in time polynomial in the number of agents, the number of indivisible goods, and 1/ϵ.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Bei, Xiaohui, Zihao Li, Jinyan Liu, Shengxin Liu, and Xinhang Lu. "Fair division of mixed divisible and indivisible goods." Artificial Intelligence 293 (April 2021): 103436. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.artint.2020.103436.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Kats, Amoz, and Yair Tauman. "Coalition production economies with divisible and indivisible inputs." Journal of Mathematical Economics 14, no. 1 (January 1985): 19–42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4068(85)90024-2.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Fallah-Moghaddam, R., and H. Moshtagh. "Radicability condition on GLn(D)." Journal of Algebra and Its Applications 17, no. 11 (November 2018): 1850203. http://dx.doi.org/10.1142/s0219498818502031.

Full text
Abstract:
Given an indivisible field [Formula: see text], let [Formula: see text] be a finite dimensional noncommutative [Formula: see text]-central division algebra. It is shown that if [Formula: see text] is radicable, then [Formula: see text] is the ordinary quaternion division algebra and [Formula: see text] is divisible. Also, it is shown that when [Formula: see text] is a field of characteristic zero and [Formula: see text], then [Formula: see text] is radicable if and only if for any field extension [Formula: see text] with [Formula: see text], [Formula: see text] is divisible.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

BASU, PARANTAP, and THOMAS I. RENSTRÖM. "OPTIMAL DYNAMIC LABOR TAXATION." Macroeconomic Dynamics 11, no. 5 (July 5, 2007): 567–88. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1365100507060221.

Full text
Abstract:
We analyze optimal dynamic taxation when labor supply is indivisible. As in Hansen (1985) and Rogerson (1988), markets are complete, and an employment lottery determines who works. The consumer can buy insurance to diversify this income uncertainty. The optimal wage tax is generally positive except for some special cases when leisure is nonnormal and the government can use debt as a policy instrument in addition to its tax instruments. We derive a HARA class of preferences, for which we characterize the dynamic paths of the wage tax. The optimal paths of the labor tax differ between divisible- and indivisible-labor economies.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Rubchinsky, Alexander. "Brams–Taylor model of fair division for divisible and indivisible items." Mathematical Social Sciences 60, no. 1 (July 2010): 1–14. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2010.03.004.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
More sources

Dissertations / Theses on the topic "Divisible and indivisible obligations"

1

Soria, Aguilar Alfredo F. "Derecho de obligaciones. Modalidades, efectos e inejecución [Capítulo 1]." Universidad Peruana de Ciencias Aplicadas (UPC), 2016. http://hdl.handle.net/10757/620865.

Full text
Abstract:
La publicación congrega a reconocidos abogados peruanos que son especialistas vinculados al Derecho de las Obligaciones. Los temas desarrollados por los autores del libro cuentan con una posición propia respecto a las modalidades, efectos e inejecución del Derecho de las Obligaciones, lo cual enriquece a esta obra, dividida en tres partes, por las distintas perspectivas sobre temas puntuales del ámbito profesional y académico.
The book brings together recognized peruvian lawyers linked to the Law of Obligations. The themes developed by the authors of the book have its own points of view over the modes, effects and non-implementation of the Law of Obligation. The perspectives of specific issues of the professional field and academic of the law increase the important of this publication divided in three parts.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Quirico, Ottavio. "Réflexions sur le système du droit international pénal - La responsabilité « pénale » des États et des autres personnes morales par rapport à celle des personnes physiques en droit international." Phd thesis, Université des Sciences Sociales - Toulouse I, 2005. http://tel.archives-ouvertes.fr/tel-00279988.

Full text
Abstract:
Par « système du droit international pénal » on entend l'ensemble des normes qui règlent la responsabilité internationale pénale. Tant au niveau des principes généraux qu'au niveau des règles relatives, les normes qui régissent la responsabilité des individus sont assez développées et cohérentes. Par contre, celles qui règlent la responsabilité des États et des autres personnes morales sont moins développées et moins cohérentes. Malgré ce décalage, la responsabilité individuelle est à la base de l'imputation collective, de sorte qu'il faut concevoir toutes les normes en question comme un système unique. En raison de la nature essentiellement privée et décentralisée du droit international, on parlerait plutôt d'un système de la responsabilité « grave » que de responsabilité « pénale », mais substantiellement, au-delà de la terminologie employée, il faut reconnaître l'existence de l'ordre normatif en question. Une évaluation dudit système, du point de vue de la cohérence (analyse ontologique) et de l'efficacité (analyse phénoménologique), dévoile un cadre problématique. Afin de sortir des impasses systématiques plusieurs solutions sont envisageables, de iure condendo. Essentiellement, on devrait réformer le système selon trois directives. En premier lieu, il faudrait définir les actes illicites internationaux graves des États de façon précise, selon l'esprit de l'article 19 du Projet d'articles sur la responsabilité des États adopté par la Commission du droit international, en première lecture, en 1996. Deuxièmement, il faudrait établir la compétence obligatoire d'une cour impartiale pour juger de la conduite des États, en coordination avec le jugement sur la responsabilité individuelle, conformément à l'imputation par le biais de l'individu-organe. Troisièmement, il faudrait créer une institution, préférablement le Conseil de sécurité des Nations Unies, capable de coordonner l'action étatique, afin de donner exécution aux décisions prises par la juridiction internationale. Finalement, la solution la plus cohérente consisterait à élargir la compétence de la Cour pénale internationale, actuellement limitée aux individus, aux États, ainsi qu'aux organisations internationales et aux autres personnes morales, dans le cadre d'une réforme radicale du système onusien. Un tel ordre, relatif de par son origine conventionnelle, pourrait être universalisé en exploitant la notion de crime en tant que violation du ius cogens. Un système ainsi conçu ne serait pas figé et statique, du point de vue du droit matériel, mais changeant et ouvert à l'inclusion de nouvelles conduites dans le champ des infractions, selon l'évolution du droit international en tant que droit vivant.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Books on the topic "Divisible and indivisible obligations"

1

Danae, Azaria. 4 The Nature of International Obligations Regarding Transit of Energy: from Bilateral to Indivisible Obligations. Oxford University Press, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/law/9780198717423.003.0004.

Full text
Abstract:
Chapter 4 classifies treaty obligations concerning transit with a view to determining which state is injured under the law of international responsibility and can invoke responsibility including by recourse to countermeasures against the responsible transit state. The question posed is to whom is each obligation owed. The analysis in this chapter also assists in determining which treaty party may have recourse to means available in the treaty where the treaty does not contain sufficiently express rules on standing, a matter which is analysed in Chapter 6. The analysis illustrates the polyphony of primary rules vis-à-vis their nature, and argues that bilateralism is not the only model in this area of international law (either in form or in substance). Rather, a number of treaties create collectively owed obligations: some erga omnes partes and some interdependent..
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Brams, Steven J. Fair Division. Edited by Donald A. Wittman and Barry R. Weingast. Oxford University Press, 2009. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199548477.003.0024.

Full text
Abstract:
This article provides a review of the literature on fair division, which has flourished in recent years. It focuses on three different literatures in the field: the allocation of several indivisible goods, the division of a single heterogeneous good, and the division, in whole or in part, of several divisible goods. The article discusses problems that arise in allocating indivisible goods, and highlights the trade-offs that must be made when not all of the criteria of fairness can be satisfied at the same time. It also describes and provides the procedures for dividing divisible goods fairly, which is based on different criteria of fairness.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Francesca, Mazza. Ch.9 Assignment of rights, transfer of obligations, assignment of contracts, s.1: Assignment of rights, Art.9.1.14. Oxford University Press, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/law/9780198702627.003.0183.

Full text
Abstract:
This commentary analyses Article 9.1.14 of the UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts (PICC) concerning rights related to the right assigned to the assignee. According to Art 9.1.14, the assignment of a right transfers to the assignee all the assignor's rights to payment or other performance under the contract in respect of the right assigned, as well as all rights securing performance of the right assigned. Art 9.1.14 is not restricted to what civil law systems would refer to as accessory rights. With respect to partial assignments, a distinction must be made between divisible rights and other rights. This commentary also discusses assignment that is contrary to a clause limiting or prohibiting assignment, along with mandatory rules and party autonomy relating to the assignee's rights to payment or other performance.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Francesca, Mazza. Ch.9 Assignment of rights, transfer of obligations, assignment of contracts, s.1: Assignment of rights, Art.9.1.4. Oxford University Press, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/law/9780198702627.003.0173.

Full text
Abstract:
This commentary analyses Article 9.1.4 of the UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts (PICC) concerning partial assignment. Art 9.1.4 recognizes the economic need for assigning part of a right. Taking into account the underlying rationale of Section 9.1 of the PICC that the assignment should not burden the obligor, Art 9.1.4 draws a distinction between a right to the payment of a monetary sum and a right to other performance. According to this provision, a right to the payment of a monetary sum may be assigned partially. A right to other performance may be assigned partially only if it is divisible, and the assignment does not render the obligation significantly more burdensome. This commentary discusses the right to the payment of a monetary sum, right to other performance, the divisibility of a right, the additional burden that a partial assignment may put on the obligor, and the effects of partial assignment on the obligee and obligor.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Baxter, Donald L. M. Hume on Space and Time. Edited by Paul Russell. Oxford University Press, 2014. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780199742844.013.7.

Full text
Abstract:
For Hume, the ideas of space and of time are each a general idea of some indivisible objects arranged in a certain manner with additional qualities that make them conceivable to the mind. He argues that the structures of these ideas reflect the structures of space and time. Thus, space and time are not infinitely divisible, and there cannot be empty space nor time without succession. Hume’s idiosyncratic theory can be seen to be reasonable if one pays careful attention to the fact that Hume, in accordance with his skepticism, is concerned only to give vent to views about space and time as they appear in experience. The chapter focuses on explicating Hume’s central arguments rather than trying to give a comprehensive treatment.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Sonja, Meier. Ch.11 Plurality of obligors and of obligees, s.1: Plurality of Obligors, Art.11.1.1. Oxford University Press, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/law/9780198702627.003.0214.

Full text
Abstract:
This commentary analyses Article 11.1.1 of the UNIDROIT Principles of International Commercial Contracts (PICC) concerning definitions related to the plurality of obligors in a contractual setting. Art 11.1.1 defines two forms of plurality of obligors, joint and several obligations and separate obligations, but does not say under which circumstances they arise. According to this article, when several obligors are bound by the same obligation towards an obligee, the obligations are joint and several when each obligor is bound for the whole obligation; the obligations are separate when each obligor is bound only for its share. The PICC therefore appear to assume that, in principle, a plurality of contractual obligors produces either joint and several, or separate obligations. This commentary discusses the requirements for the plurality of obligors, joint and several obligations, separate obligations, and types of plurality not mentioned in Article 11.1.1, namely indivisible obligations, communal obligations, and accessory obligations.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Danae, Azaria. 9 General Conclusion. Oxford University Press, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/law/9780198717423.003.0009.

Full text
Abstract:
Faced with the need to cooperate in order to access energy sources and energy markets, states increasingly conclude treaties with a view to guaranteeing uninterrupted transit of energy via pipelines. Although bilateralisable treaty obligations regarding transit of energy remain dominant, a trend towards genuinely multilateral obligations regarding transit is appearing in treaty practice, along with a trend of multilateralization on an institutional level. The indivisible nature of obligations and the emphasis that treaty parties place on uninterrupted energy flows via each pipeline may signal a trend away from unilateralism- countermeasures remain a preferred a means of implementing responsibility, but treaty rules are being established that may prohibit unilateral countermeasures, as circumstances precluding wrongfulness.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Danae, Azaria. Treaties on Transit of Energy via Pipelines and Countermeasures. Oxford University Press, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/law/9780198717423.001.0001.

Full text
Abstract:
This monograph examines the relationship between treaties providing for uninterrupted energy transit and countermeasures under the law of international responsibility. It analyses the obligations governing energy transit through pipelines in multilateral and bilateral treaties, looking at the WTO Agreement, the Energy Charter Treaty, and sixteen bespoke pipeline treaties. It argues that a number of transit obligations under these treaties are indivisible, reflecting the collective interests of states parties. The analysis is placed in the historical and normative landscape of freedom of transit in international law. After setting out the content and scope of obligations concerning transit of energy, it distinguishes countermeasures from treaty law responses, and examines the dispute settlement and compliance supervision provisions in these treaties. Building on these findings, the work discusses the availability and lawfulness of countermeasures as, on the one hand, a means of implementing the transit state’s responsibility for interruptions of energy transit via pipelines; and, on the other hand, circumstances that preclude the wrongfulness of the transit state’s interruptions of transit. The competing interests of the transit state and those of the states dependent on the pipeline make this question one of the most controversial aspects of modern international law.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Book chapters on the topic "Divisible and indivisible obligations"

1

"THE INDIVISIBLE AND THE DIVISIBLE." In Ever Smaller. The MIT Press, 2020. http://dx.doi.org/10.7551/mitpress/11622.003.0004.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

"14 Allocating Divisible and Indivisible Goods." In Mathematics and Democracy, 305–28. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2008. http://dx.doi.org/10.1515/9781400835591.305.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Schmaltz, Tad M. "Material Monism and Bodily Parts." In The Metaphysics of the Material World, 225–66. Oxford University Press, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780190070229.003.0007.

Full text
Abstract:
This chapter addresses the question of whether Spinoza’s reference to finite bodies as “parts” that compose an infinite material nature is compatible with the implication of his monism that extended substance is indivisible. There is particular emphasis on the distinctively Spinozistic notion of a “modal part.” It is argued that though Spinoza requires that substantial quantity is indivisible, he holds that quantity can also be conceived to be a modal whole that is divisible into modal parts. The account of this latter sort of quantity is related to Spinoza’s view that nature as a whole can be considered to be an infinite mode that is itself an “individual” that comprises all finite bodily individuals as its parts. The chapter closes with a consideration of the implication of Spinoza’s mereology that the relation of parts to the wholes they compose is weaker than the relation of modes to what they modify.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Levey, Samuel. "Continuous Extension and Indivisibles in Galileo." In The History of Continua, 82–103. Oxford University Press, 2020. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780198809647.003.0005.

Full text
Abstract:
This chapter studies Galileo’s account of continuous extension and his pioneering use of indivisibles in the analysis of paradoxes of infinity and continuity. Galileo’s treatment presents continuous magnitudes as composed of finite ever-divisible parts as well as infinitely many indivisible elements he calls partes non quanti. Special scrutiny is given to Galileo’s analysis of the paradox of Aristotle’s wheel as well as to Galileo’s account of continuous uniform and accelerated motion as it occurs in the Dialogo (1632) and the Discorsi (1638). Galileo’s discussion is illuminated by comparison with the techniques of Cavalieri and Huygens.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Antognazza, Maria Rosa. "8. Monads." In Leibniz: A Very Short Introduction, 85–99. Oxford University Press, 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/actrade/9780198718642.003.0008.

Full text
Abstract:
From 1695 Leibniz came to the view that the best way to capture what it is to be a substance is through the concept of ‘monad’. ‘Monad’, Leibniz explained, comes from the Greek monas ‘which signifies unity, or that which is one’. ‘Monads’ outlines Leibniz’s counter-intuitive metaphysical model by explaining his definitions of unity, simplicity, activity, force, perception, and appetite. His view was that simple, immaterial, non-extended, indivisible entities are the condition of the existence of composed, material, extended, divisible entities. The world of extended bodies studied by physics is ultimately intelligible only if we postulate metaphysical entities that must exist in order for those extended bodies to exist.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Singh, Zorawar Daulet. "Indira Gandhi’s Role Conception." In Power and Diplomacy, 193–221. Oxford University Press, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/oso/9780199489640.003.0006.

Full text
Abstract:
This chapter reconstructs Indira Gandhi’s role conception by analysing the Prime Minister and her core advisors’ public and private communication record. Indira Gandhi’s regional role conception of India as a security seeker, it is contended, was shaped by three core inter-related beliefs: a definition of India’s interests in more narrow terms compared to Nehru’s beliefs, and, a regional image centred on the subcontinent rather than on an extended Asian space that lay at the heart of Nehru’s image; a divisible conception of security rather than an indivisible one, and an inclination to leverage the balance of power for geopolitical advantage rather than to reform Asia’s interaction culture as per Nehru’s role conception; and, an inclination to employ coercive means to solve disputes or to pursue geopolitical ends in South Asia rather than a preference for ethical statecraft and strategic restraint embodied in Nehru’s worldview.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Hilal, Elver. "Part II Predominant Security Challenges and International Law, Economic and Resource Security, Ch.27 Food Security." In The Oxford Handbook of the International Law of Global Security. Oxford University Press, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/law/9780198827276.003.0028.

Full text
Abstract:
This chapter focuses on food security. Although ‘food security’ is not a legal concept and does not impose rights or responsibilities, it is a necessary precondition to the full enjoyment of the right to food. The right to food is enshrined in article 25 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights as an integral part of the right to an adequate standard of living. As this right is indivisible, interrelated, and interdependent with all other fundamental rights and freedoms, it is ultimately essential for a secure, safe, and harmonious world. The chapter demonstrates that severe food insecurity continues to inflict massive casualties and create and prolong conflicts and emergencies despite well-established rules of international law, international humanitarian law, and international human rights law. It then looks at the international law principles protecting food security with the aim to diffuse emergency situations that create instability, inequality, and unrest, including those resulting from conflicts and natural disasters. The chapter provides suggestions for enforcing and enhancing existing laws and for the adoption of a new international convention which will set out clear duties and obligations for States and non-State actors with a view to eliminating food insecurity and preventing violations of the right to food for a safer, more secure world.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Conference papers on the topic "Divisible and indivisible obligations"

1

Hu, Menglan, and Bharadwaj Veeravalli. "Scheduling hybrid divisible and indivisible loads on clusters." In 2011 17th IEEE International Conference on Networks (ICON). IEEE, 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/icon.2011.6168521.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Jie Hu and Raymond Klefstad. "Scheduling multiple divisible and indivisible tasks on bus networks." In 2007 IEEE International Conference on Cluster Computing (CLUSTER). IEEE, 2007. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/clustr.2007.4629235.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!

To the bibliography