To see the other types of publications on this topic, follow the link: Friedrich Hayek.

Journal articles on the topic 'Friedrich Hayek'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the top 50 journal articles for your research on the topic 'Friedrich Hayek.'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Browse journal articles on a wide variety of disciplines and organise your bibliography correctly.

1

Horwitz, Steven. "Friedrich Hayek, Austrian Economist." Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27, no. 1 (March 2005): 71–85. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09557570500031604.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Howson, S. "Friedrich Hayek: A Biography." History of Political Economy 35, no. 2 (June 1, 2003): 346–48. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-35-2-346.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

O'Brien, D. P. "Friedrich Hayek: A Biography." Economic Journal 112, no. 483 (November 1, 2002): F581—F583. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.t01-23-00083.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Nadeau, Robert. "L’évolutionnisme économique de Friedrich Hayek." Philosophiques 25, no. 2 (August 8, 2007): 257–79. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/027490ar.

Full text
Abstract:
RÉSUMÉ Une analyse minutieuse du dernier ouvrage de Hayek publié quatre ans avant sa mort, soit en 1988 (La Présomption fatale), permet de mettre au Jour les tenants et aboutissants de la perspective évolutionnaire épousée par Hayek en matière d'économie politique. Examinant d'abord le concept d'ordre spontané, exposant ensuite le fonctionnement de Véconomie marchande comme système en expansion continue, je montre alors comment s'articulent pour Hayek compétence économique et compétence épistémique d'un côté, puis coordination économique et compétence morale de l'autre. L'analyse fait apercevoir que, fondamentalement, l'optique de Hayek est évolutionnaire parce qu 'elle est résolument populationnelle, ce que les commentateurs de Hayek ont plutôt ignoré jusqu'ici, ce qui fournit l'occasion de passer en revue les critiques adressées par Hayek au principe de population de Malthus (1798).
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Ikeda, Yukihiro. "Friedrich Hayek on Social Justice: Taking Hayek Seriously." History of Economics Review 57, no. 1 (December 2013): 32–46. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/18386318.2013.11681245.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Hodgson, Geoffrey M. "Hayek's Theory of Cultural Evolution: An Evaluation in the Light of Vanberg's Critique." Economics and Philosophy 7, no. 1 (April 1991): 67–82. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s0266267100000912.

Full text
Abstract:
The application of evolutionary ideas to socioeconomic systems has been an increasingly prominent theme in the work of Friedrich Hayek, and the motif has become dominant in his recent book (Hayek, 1988). In an earlier issue of this journal, Viktor Vanberg (1986) raises two substantive criticisms of Friedrich Hayek' theory of cultural evolution that invoke some important questions concerning use of the evolutionary analogy in social science.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Garrison, Roger W., and G. R. Steele. "The Economics of Friedrich Hayek." Southern Economic Journal 61, no. 4 (April 1995): 1234. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1060759.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Steele, G. R. "FRIEDRICH HAYEK: THE COMPLETE ECONOMIST." Economic Affairs 28, no. 2 (June 2008): 67–69. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0270.2008.00829.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Kirzner, Israel M. "Friedrich A. Hayek 1899–1992." Critical Review 5, no. 4 (September 1991): 585–92. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/08913819108443245.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Urgacz, Paweł. "Friedrich August von Hayek: Konstytucja wolności." Forum Philosophicum 13, no. 1 (June 1, 2008): 149–54. http://dx.doi.org/10.35765/forphil.2008.1301.12.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
11

Voigt, Stefan. "The Legacy of Friedrich Von Hayek." Economic Systems 25, no. 4 (December 2001): 408–14. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s0939-3625(01)00037-1.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
12

Mahoney, Michael J., and Walter B. Weimer. "Friedrich A. Hayek (1899–1992): Obituary." American Psychologist 49, no. 1 (1994): 63. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/0003-066x.49.1.63.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
13

Spicer, Michael W. "On Friedrich Hayek and Public Administration." Administration & Society 25, no. 1 (May 1993): 46–59. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/009539979302500103.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
14

Maskin, Eric S. "Friedrich von Hayek and mechanism design." Review of Austrian Economics 28, no. 3 (April 12, 2015): 247–52. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11138-015-0310-3.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
15

Kula, Erhun. "Book Review: Friedrich Hayek: A Biography." Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 14, no. 3 (July 2003): 311–13. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/02601079x03001400306.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
16

Gamel, Claude. "La dialectique libérale de Friedrich Hayek." Austriaca, no. 90 (June 1, 2020): 155–72. http://dx.doi.org/10.4000/austriaca.1367.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
17

GICK, EVELYN, and PETRIK RUNST. "INTRODUCTION AND COMMENTARY FOR F. A. HAYEK’S “THE OVERRATED REASON”." Journal of the History of Economic Thought 35, no. 2 (May 10, 2013): 233–37. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1053837213000084.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
18

Ebeling, Richard M. "Hayek e Mises:." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 2, no. 2 (December 1, 2014): 629–50. http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2014.v2.697.

Full text
Abstract:
O artigo explica a sua relação pessoal e profissional entre Friedrich A. Hayek e Ludwig von Mises durante o período entre as duas Guerras Mundiais e, também explica as concepções destes dois economistas sobre processo de mercado, papel do conhecimento, preços e expectativas empreendedoras na tendência de produzir coordenação do mercado competitivo. Além disso, discute aquelas áreas nas quais suas abordagens para tais questões eram complementares, o mesmo não acontecendo no que diz respeito à formação de expectativas no processo de mercado.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
19

De Vlieghere, Martin. "A Reappraisal of Friedrich A. Hayek's Cultural Evolutionism." Economics and Philosophy 10, no. 2 (October 1994): 285–304. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s0266267100004752.

Full text
Abstract:
In spite of the important discoveries made by Adam Smith and later by the economists of the Austrian School, Friedrich Hayek remained intellectually challenged by the miracle of the price mechanism. As it turned out there was still some pioneering to do in describing the price mechanism. This became clear when Hayek identified the dispersal of information relevant to exchange transactions as the central issue of economic study. In the context of his distinction between competition as a state of things and as a process (Hayek, [1946]1980, pp. 92–106) the price mechanism manifests itself as a powerful integrator of information which is at first sight hopelessly dispersed in modern society. In 1945 he pointed out another intellectual challenge which the miracle of the price mechanism poses: How could such a marvelous functionality come into existence? “I am convinced that if it [the price mechanism] were the result of deliberate human design, and if the people guided by the price changes understood that their decisions have significance far beyond their immediate aim, this mechanism would have been acclaimed as one of the greatest triumphs of the human mind” (Hayek, [1945]1980, p. 87). It is precisely because the free determination of prices is obviously not an invention, and because actors on the market in general do not realize that their decisions are at once also signals for the information-processing system that the market is, that in general this market order is not highly estimated. The market order is nevertheless the best illustration of the dual principle that the most beautiful forms of complex functionality are not deliberately created and are not deliberately maintained (“the twin ideas of evolution and spontaneous order,” as Hayek put it; Hayek [1978]1985, p. 250; [1979] 1982, p. 158).
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
20

Vergara Estévez, Jorge. "La concepción del hombre de Friedrich Hayek." Polisemia 5, no. 8 (December 1, 2009): 59–72. http://dx.doi.org/10.26620/uniminuto.polisemia.5.8.2009.59-72.

Full text
Abstract:
En este artículo se expone los aspectos centrales de la concepción del hombre de Hayek y sus principales antecedentes intelectuales. El pensador austriaco desarrolla dicha concepción en dos planos. De una parte, ofrece una concepción de lo qué es el hombre: un ser individualista, cuya evolución histórica conduce desde “la sociedad tribal” a la “sociedad extendida”, y es un ser creador de normas y tradiciones. De otra, cómo es, se caracterizan sus dimensiones principales: su ética es heterónoma e inmanente a la reproducción de la sociedad; su razón es limitada; la libertad es su valor central, aunque se limita a la libertad económica y, finalmente, sostiene que los hombres son naturalmente desiguales.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
21

Bowles, Samuel, Alan Kirman, and Rajiv Sethi. "Retrospectives: Friedrich Hayek and the Market Algorithm." Journal of Economic Perspectives 31, no. 3 (August 1, 2017): 215–30. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.31.3.215.

Full text
Abstract:
Friedrich A. Hayek (1899–1992) is known for his vision of the market economy as an information processing system characterized by spontaneous order: the emergence of coherence through the independent actions of large numbers of individuals, each with limited and local knowledge, coordinated by prices that arise from decentralized processes of competition. Hayek is also known for his advocacy of a broad range of free market policies and, indeed, considered the substantially unregulated market system to be superior to competing alternatives precisely because it made the best use of dispersed knowledge. Our purpose in writing this paper is twofold: First, we believe that Hayek's economic vision and critique of equilibrium theory not only remain relevant, but apply with greater force as information has become ever more central to economic activity and the complexity of the information aggregation process has become increasingly apparent. Second, we wish to call into question Hayek's belief that his advocacy of free market policies follows as a matter of logic from his economic vision. The very usefulness of prices (and other economic variables) as informative messages—which is the centerpiece of Hayek's economics—creates incentives to extract information from signals in ways that can be destabilizing. Markets can promote prosperity but can also generate crises. We will argue, accordingly, that a Hayekian understanding of the economy as an information-processing system does not support the type of policy positions that he favored. Thus, we find considerable lasting value in Hayek's economic analysis while nonetheless questioning the connection of this analysis to his political philosophy.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
22

Grant, David M. "Hayek's Journey: The Mind of Friedrich Hayek." American Journal of Economics and Sociology 63, no. 4 (October 2004): 943–46. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1536-7150.2004.00326.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
23

Howson, S. "Hayek's Journey: The Mind of Friedrich Hayek." History of Political Economy 38, no. 3 (September 1, 2006): 555–56. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-2006-008.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
24

Caldwell, Bruce, and Leonidas Montes. "Friedrich Hayek and his visits to Chile." Review of Austrian Economics 28, no. 3 (September 26, 2014): 261–309. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11138-014-0290-8.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
25

Jacobs, Struan, and Phil Mullins. "Friedrich Hayek and Michael Polanyi in Correspondence." History of European Ideas 42, no. 1 (February 12, 2015): 107–30. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01916599.2014.1002971.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
26

Jacobs, Struan. "Spontaneous order: Michael Polanyi and Friedrich Hayek." Critical Review of International Social and Political Philosophy 3, no. 4 (December 2000): 49–67. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13698230008403329.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
27

Sabooglu, Müfit. "Hayek and Spontaneous Orders." Journal of the History of Economic Thought 18, no. 2 (1996): 347–64. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1053837200003321.

Full text
Abstract:
Friedrich A. Hayek's work spans over more than forty years and encompasses a number of social disciplines. That work has a single goal, however: the justification of a liberal social order. Apart from the justification of the liberal order, two other elements of his work in particular draw the attention of many economists: his definition of the economic problem as being one of coordination, and his effort to explain certain social phenomena as the result of a spontaneous order.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
28

Gappo, Patrick Coelho Campos. "Justiça Social no Pensamento de Friedrich Hayek – Parte I." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 4, no. 1 (June 1, 2016): 209–23. http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2016.v4.839.

Full text
Abstract:
Discute-se a questão da justiça social no pensamento de Friedrich A. Hayek, começando por um panorama do pensamento liberal, buscando demonstrar como o autor se insere nesse contexto intelectual. Em seguida, apresentamos os principais conceitos da filosofia política de Hayek e finalmente usamos essa base para discutir a negação que o pensador austríaco faz sobre o conceito de justiça social. Concluímos com algumas reflexões sobre os temas abordados e a ordem de mercado.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
29

Hayek, Friedrich August von. "Discurso no Banquete de Gala." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 2, no. 2 (December 1, 2014): 593–94. http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2014.v2.689.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
30

Hayek, Friedrich August von. "A Pretensão do Conhecimento." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 2, no. 2 (December 1, 2014): 595–603. http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2014.v2.691.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
31

Nogueira, Jorge Henrique de Saules. "Breves Notas sobre a Epistemologia de Friedrich A. von Hayek." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 4, no. 1 (June 1, 2016): 31–51. http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2016.v4.817.

Full text
Abstract:
A abordagem epistemológica de Hayek aponta para a falibilidade, a ignorância e a fragmentação do conhecimento na sociedade. Sua epistemologia se estrutura de forma a revelar a impossibilidade da construção de ordens sociais desejáveis a partir da deliberada vontade humana dirigida a esse fim. A compreensão da epistemologia de Hayek contribui para rediscutir dogmas cristalizados nas áreas de ciências humanas e sociais, servindo de poderoso contraponto ao pensamento reinante no proscênio político, jurídico e acadêmico brasileiro.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
32

Bourdeau, Michel. "Friedrich A. HAYEK, The Market and Other Orders." Revue européenne des sciences sociales, no. 53-2 (November 15, 2015): 259–62. http://dx.doi.org/10.4000/ress.3150.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
33

Rugina, Anghel N. "8. Nobel Laureate: Friedrich A. Hayek (1899‐1992)." International Journal of Social Economics 30, no. 4 (April 2003): 559–80. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/03068290310764407.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
34

Lewis, Paul. "Emergent properties in the work of Friedrich Hayek." Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 82, no. 2-3 (May 2012): 368–78. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2011.04.009.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
35

Salerno, Joseph T. "Mises e Hayek Desomogeneizados." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 2, no. 2 (December 1, 2014): 651–76. http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2014.v2.699.

Full text
Abstract:
Desde seu renascimento no início dos anos 1970, o que veio a se chamar de “Economia Austríaca” tem sido considerado, pela maior parte de seus adeptos contemporâneos, como a continuação de uma tradição unificada que pode ser rastreada até Carl Menger. Este artigo desafia essa perspectiva e argumenta que, de fato, duas tradições muito diferentes emergiram do trabalho de Menger. Uma tradição pode ser rastreada, através da obra de F. A. Hayek, a Friedrich Wieser, um dos dois seguidores mais proeminentes de Menger. A outra tradição emana dos escritos do outro discípulo principal de Menger, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, e inclui seu aluno Ludwig von Mises. Este ensaio defende a tese de que essas duas tradições separadas existem e foram confundidas pelos austríacos modernos.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
36

De la Nuez Sánchez-Cascado, Paloma. "El liberalismo de Friedrich A. Hayek y Judith N. Shklar: una comparación." Araucaria, no. 41 (2019): 37–60. http://dx.doi.org/10.12795/araucaria.2019.i41.02.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
37

Sanz Bas, David. "Hayek and the cryptocurrency revolution." Iberian Journal of the History of Economic Thought 7, no. 1 (May 12, 2020): 15–28. http://dx.doi.org/10.5209/ijhe.69403.

Full text
Abstract:
The emergence of cryptocurrencies has been one of the most notable monetary phenomenon of the last decade. Many academics and analysts have found a clear precedent to this event in Friedrich Hayek's latest monetary work, Denationalization of money. The aim of this article is to analyze what we can learn about cryptocurrencies by re-reading this book. As will be proven, Hayek would surely have rejected the idea that Bitcoin and cryptocurrencies with similar characteristics could be accepted as money in the market. Furthermore, this paper will prove that a very close connection between Stablecoins and private money exists, following the Austrian economist’s predictions in a context of monetary competition.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
38

Shearmur, Jeremy. "Hayek, The Road to Serfdom, and the British Conservatives." Journal of the History of Economic Thought 28, no. 3 (September 2006): 309–14. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10427710600857807.

Full text
Abstract:
Over the years, Friedrich Hayek has received a generous response from some members of the British Conservative Party. One immediately thinks of endorsements of his work by Mrs. Thatcher in the 1970s and '80s.Those with longer memories—and teeth—might also recall the controversy around Winston Churchill's first election broadcast in 1945, and the response to it by the Labour leader Clement Attlee, the following evening. Churchill spoke of the dangers of planning, and raised the idea that it would, in the end, require the powers of a Gestapo to put the ideal of a planned society into practice. Attlee criticized these ideas, and Hayek as the source of the theoretical conceptions behind them. This led to a fair bit of attention being paid to Hayek by the press, and to his being described as an economic adviser to Churchill. But Hayek himself has downplayed his direct contacts with Churchill (cf. Hayek 1994, pp. 106–107). Indeed, in Hayek on Hayek (Hayek 1994), Hayek indicates that he met Churchill only once. On that occasion he was struck by Churchill's being the worse for drink and then recovering, to Hayek's surprise, to make a first-rate speech.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
39

Angner, Erik. "Did Hayek Commit the Naturalistic Fallacy?" Journal of the History of Economic Thought 26, no. 3 (September 2004): 349–61. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/1042771042000263830.

Full text
Abstract:
In promoting spontaneous orders—orders that evolve in a process of cultural evolution—as “efficient,” “beneficial,” and “advantageous,” Friedrich A. Hayek (1899–1992) has often been attributed the belief that there is something desirable about them. For this reason, he has been accused of committing the naturalistic fallacy, that is, of trying to derive an “ought” from an “is.” It appears that Hayek was quite aware of the charge, and vigorously disputed it: “I have no intention to commit what is often called the genetic or naturalistic fallacy” (1988, p. 27).
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
40

Vidal Robson, José A. "Conservadurismo y liberalismo económico. La crítica de Scruton a Hayek." Tópicos, Revista de Filosofía, no. 61 (June 23, 2021): 321–49. http://dx.doi.org/10.21555/top.v0i61.1200.

Full text
Abstract:
El propósito de este artículo es analizar el modo en que se vincula el conservadurismo y el liberalismo económico a partir de la crítica de Roger Scruton a Friedrich A. Hayek. Primero se analizan los conceptos de libertad negativa, orden espontáneo y catalaxia en Hayek; luego, se presenta la crítica del filósofo inglés al austriaco; y, por último, se presenta la teoría social-económica de Scruton como un modo de respuesta a las tensiones del liberalismo económico.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
41

Ferreira, Fernanda Gomes. "Liberdade, Democracia e Relações Internacionais em Friedrich A. Hayek." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 3, no. 2 (December 1, 2015): 557–63. http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2015.v3.797.

Full text
Abstract:
A proposta de nosso artigo é apresentar algumas considerações sobre a obra de Friedrich A. Hayek, um importante autor da teoria política contemporânea. Abordaremos alguns dos pontos fundamentais de seu pensamento, entre os quais, seu conceito de liberdade individual, suas reflexões sobre a democracia, e o Estado liberal. Pretendemos também, no campo das relações internacionais, tratar das perspectivas do autor sobre a ordem internacional no período posterior a segunda guerra mundial.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
42

Gappo, Patrick Coelho Campos. "Justiça Social no Pensamento de Friedrich Hayek - Parte II." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 4, no. 2 (December 1, 2016): 495–521. http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2016.v4.155.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
43

Châton, Gwendal. "Libéralisme ou démocratie ? Raymond Aron lecteur de Friedrich Hayek." Revue de philosophie économique 17, no. 1 (2016): 103. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/rpec.171.0103.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
44

Yolal, Merve. "Friedrich August von Hayek Perspektifinden İktidarın Gücü ve Sınırları." Eskişehir Osmangazi Üniversitesi İktisadi ve İdari Bilimler Dergisi 13, no. 2 (August 15, 2018): 119–32. http://dx.doi.org/10.17153/oguiibf.395090.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
45

Botto, Michele. "Mercado y sociedad: la utopía política de Friedrich Hayek." Polisemia 11, no. 20 (August 4, 2016): 93–96. http://dx.doi.org/10.26620/uniminuto.polisemia.11.20.2015.93-96.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
46

Onofre, Gabriel. "Friedrich Hayek e os Liberais Brasileiros na Transição Democrática." Revista Crítica Histórica 5, no. 10 (2014): 194–216. http://dx.doi.org/10.28998/rchvl5n10.2014.0011.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
47

KÖSE, SEVDA. "SOSYAL ADALETİN İKİ LİBERAL YÜZÜ: JOHN RAWLS FRIEDRICH HAYEK." Journal of International Social Research 9, no. 43 (April 20, 2016): 812. http://dx.doi.org/10.17719/jisr.20164317652.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
48

Boily, Frédéric, and Natalie Boisvert. "Le libéralisme de l’inquiétude : Friedrich Hayek et Judith Shklar1." Articles 33, no. 3 (January 7, 2015): 3–29. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/1027938ar.

Full text
Abstract:
Ce texte propose une analyse de certaines dimensions de la pensée de deux auteurs libéraux, Friedrich A. Hayek et Judith N. Shklar, qui ont été rarement analysés ensemble et, parfois même, ont été oubliés, notamment dans le cas de la seconde. Il s’agit de montrer, à partir de la notion de l’inquiétude, que ces deux libéraux illustrent un aspect de la diversité de la pensée libérale, et ce, à partir d’une même appréhension critique à l’égard des capacités de la raison. Or, si Hayek et Shklar s’entendaient sur les profondes limitations de la raison humaine à maîtriser les flux sociaux, nous montrons que ces deux auteurs divergent quant à l’orientation générale qu’ils donnent au libéralisme. Alors que le libéralisme de la peur de Shklar l’amenait à vouloir réconcilier le libéralisme avec un État palliant les injustices subies par les opprimés, celui d’Hayek l’entraînait plutôt à dénoncer les mirages de la justice sociale.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
49

Samuelson, Paul A. "A few remembrances of Friedrich von Hayek (1899–1992)." Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 69, no. 1 (January 2009): 1–4. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2008.07.001.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
50

Griffiths, Simon. "Engaging enemies: Exploring the left's fascination with Friedrich Hayek." Juncture 21, no. 3 (December 2014): 204–9. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.2050-5876.2014.00806.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!

To the bibliography