To see the other types of publications on this topic, follow the link: Intertemporal decisions.

Journal articles on the topic 'Intertemporal decisions'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the top 50 journal articles for your research on the topic 'Intertemporal decisions.'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Browse journal articles on a wide variety of disciplines and organise your bibliography correctly.

1

Chiappori, Pierre-Andre, and Maurizio Mazzocco. "Static and Intertemporal Household Decisions." Journal of Economic Literature 55, no. 3 (2017): 985–1045. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jel.20150715.

Full text
Abstract:
We discuss the most popular static and dynamic models of household behavior. Our main objective is to explain which aspects of household decisions different models can account for. Using this insight, we describe testable implications, identification results, and estimation findings obtained in the literature. Particular attention is given to the ability of different models to answer various types of policy questions. (JEL D11, D13, D15, I38)
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Dshemuchadse, Maja, Stefan Scherbaum, and Thomas Goschke. "How decisions emerge: Action dynamics in intertemporal decision making." Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 142, no. 1 (2013): 93–100. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/a0028499.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Foerde, Karin, Bernd Figner, Bradley B. Doll, et al. "Dopamine Modulation of Intertemporal Decision-making: Evidence from Parkinson Disease." Journal of Cognitive Neuroscience 28, no. 5 (2016): 657–67. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/jocn_a_00929.

Full text
Abstract:
Choosing between smaller prompt rewards and larger later rewards is a common choice problem, and studies widely agree that frontostriatal circuits heavily innervated by dopamine are centrally involved. Understanding how dopamine modulates intertemporal choice has important implications for neurobiological models and for understanding the mechanisms underlying maladaptive decision-making. However, the specific role of dopamine in intertemporal decisions is not well understood. Dopamine may play a role in multiple aspects of intertemporal choices—the valuation of choice outcomes and sensitivity
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Heilman, Renata M., Petko Kusev, Mircea Miclea, et al. "Are Impulsive Decisions Always Irrational? An Experimental Investigation of Impulsive Decisions in the Domains of Gains and Losses." International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 18, no. 16 (2021): 8518. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/ijerph18168518.

Full text
Abstract:
Intertemporal choices are very prevalent in daily life, ranging from simple, mundane decisions to highly consequential decisions. In this context, thinking about the future and making sound decisions are crucial to promoting mental and physical health, as well as a financially sustainable lifestyle. In the present study, we set out to investigate some of the possible underlying mechanisms, such as cognitive factors and emotional states, that promote future-oriented decisions. In a cross-sectional experimental study, we used a gain and a loss version of an intertemporal monetary choices task. O
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Rogerson, William P. "Intertemporal Cost Allocation and Investment Decisions." Journal of Political Economy 116, no. 5 (2008): 931–50. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/591909.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Wang, Jianli, and Jingyuan Li. "Comparative Ambiguity Aversion in Intertemporal Decisions." Journal of Risk and Insurance 87, no. 1 (2018): 195–212. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jori.12253.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Lumpkin, G. T., and Keith H. Brigham. "Long–Term Orientation and Intertemporal Choice in Family Firms." Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice 35, no. 6 (2011): 1149–69. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6520.2011.00495.x.

Full text
Abstract:
A long–term orientation (LTO) is often associated with family firms, but the LTO construct is underdeveloped. This paper sets forth a framework for studying LTO in family firms including developing three dimensions—futurity, continuity, and perseverance. It identifies LTO as a higher–order heuristic that, in matters of intertemporal choice, provides a dominant logic for decisions and actions. Intertemporal choice refers to decisions with payoffs or outcomes that play out over time. Three mechanisms affecting intertemporal choices are identified—representation, self–control, and anticipation. L
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Cheng, Jiuqing. "THE ROLE OF NUMERACY AND IMPULSIVITY IN INTERTEMPORAL CHOICE AND DECISION MAKING." Psychological Thought 13, no. 1 (2020): 254–72. http://dx.doi.org/10.37708/psyct.v13i1.442.

Full text
Abstract:
A growing body of research has indicated a relationship between numeracy and decision making and that lower numerate people display more disadvantageous decisions. In the domain of intertemporal choice, researchers have long been using impulsivity to address choice preference. To further illuminate the psychological mechanisms of making intertemporal choices, the present study examined the role of impulsivity and numeracy in intertemporal choice, in the presence of each other. The study adopted both subjective and numeracy scales. These scales correlated with each other and with intertemporal
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Glätzle-Rützler, Daniela, Philipp Lergetporer, and Matthias Sutter. "Collective intertemporal decisions and heterogeneity in groups." Games and Economic Behavior 130 (November 2021): 131–47. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2021.07.009.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Patt, Virginie M., Renee Hunsberger, Dominoe A. Jones, Margaret M. Keane, and Mieke Verfaellie. "Temporal discounting when outcomes are experienced in the moment: Validation of a novel paradigm and comparison with a classic hypothetical intertemporal choice task." PLOS ONE 16, no. 5 (2021): e0251480. http://dx.doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0251480.

Full text
Abstract:
When faced with intertemporal choices, people typically devalue rewards available in the future compared to rewards more immediately available, a phenomenon known as temporal discounting. Decisions involving intertemporal choices arise daily, with critical impact on health and financial wellbeing. Although many such decisions are “experiential” in that they involve delays and rewards that are experienced in real-time and can inform subsequent choices, most studies have focused on intertemporal choices with hypothetical outcomes (or outcomes delivered after all decisions are made). The present
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
11

Mitchell, Jason P., Jessica Schirmer, Daniel L. Ames, and Daniel T. Gilbert. "Medial Prefrontal Cortex Predicts Intertemporal Choice." Journal of Cognitive Neuroscience 23, no. 4 (2011): 857–66. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/jocn.2010.21479.

Full text
Abstract:
People often make shortsighted decisions to receive small benefits in the present rather than large benefits in the future, that is, to favor their current selves over their future selves. In two studies using fMRI, we demonstrated that people make such decisions in part because they fail to engage in the same degree of self-referential processing when thinking about their future selves. When participants predicted how much they would enjoy an event in the future, they showed less activity in brain regions associated with introspective self-reference—such as the ventromedial pFC (vMPFC)—than w
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
12

Hurwicz, Leonid, and Mukul Majumdar. "Optimal intertemporal allocation mechanisms and decentralization of decisions." Journal of Economic Theory 45, no. 2 (1988): 228–61. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(88)90268-2.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
13

Lu, Wei, Yuwei Zhou, Li Sunny Pan, and Yuhao Zhao. "Hungry people cannot take care of their future: impact of hunger on intertemporal choice." Journal of Contemporary Marketing Science 2, no. 3 (2019): 233–45. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/jcmars-02-2019-0014.

Full text
Abstract:
Purpose People often need to make intertemporal choices in their daily life, such as savings and spending, but their decisions are not always entirely rational. The purpose of this paper is to study the effect of hunger on intertemporal choices and the moderating effect of sensitivity to reward. Design/methodology/approach Two studies verified these two hypotheses. The first study confirmed the existence of the main effect by manipulating food aroma. In the second study, by manipulating hunger with images, the authors increased external validity of the study and confirmed the regulation of the
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
14

Alcantud, José, and María Muñoz Torrecillas. "Intertemporal Choice of Fuzzy Soft Sets." Symmetry 10, no. 9 (2018): 371. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/sym10090371.

Full text
Abstract:
This paper first merges two noteworthy aspects of choice. On the one hand, soft sets and fuzzy soft sets are popular models that have been largely applied to decision making problems, such as real estate valuation, medical diagnosis (glaucoma, prostate cancer, etc.), data mining, or international trade. They provide crisp or fuzzy parameterized descriptions of the universe of alternatives. On the other hand, in many decisions, costs and benefits occur at different points in time. This brings about intertemporal choices, which may involve an indefinitely large number of periods. However, the li
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
15

Li, Hongxia, and Guoquan Chen. "Benevolence–dependability value and intertemporal choice: Moderating effect of perceived socioeconomic status." Social Behavior and Personality: an international journal 46, no. 9 (2018): 1573–83. http://dx.doi.org/10.2224/sbp.6826.

Full text
Abstract:
We recruited 118 university student participants from Beijing to examine how the benevolence–dependability value affects intertemporal choice and how perceived socioeconomic status moderates this relationship. The results showed that participants' benevolence–dependability value positively predicted their intertemporal choice, and that perceived socioeconomic status moderated this relationship. Further, the benevolence–dependability value of individuals of higher perceived socioeconomic status did not have a significant effect on intertemporal choice. In contrast, the benevolence–dependability
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
16

Wittmann, Marc, and Martin P. Paulus. "Intertemporal choice: Neuronal and psychological determinants of economic decisions." Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics 2, no. 2 (2009): 71–74. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/a0017695.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
17

Glomm, Gerhard, and Michael G. Palumbo. "Optimal intertemporal consumption decisions under the threat of starvation." Journal of Development Economics 42, no. 2 (1993): 271–91. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(93)90021-e.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
18

de Oliveira, Angela C. M., and Sarah Jacobson. "(Im)patience by proxy: Making intertemporal decisions for others." Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 182 (February 2021): 83–99. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2020.12.008.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
19

Kim, Kyu, and Gal Zauberman. "The effect of music tempo on consumer impatience in intertemporal decisions." European Journal of Marketing 53, no. 3 (2019): 504–23. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/ejm-10-2017-0696.

Full text
Abstract:
Purpose This paper aims to examine the effect of music tempo on impatience in intertemporal tradeoff decisions. It finds that fast (vs slow) tempo music increases impatience. This occurs because fast (vs slow) tempo music makes temporal distance, and hence the waiting time until the receipt of delayed benefits, feel subjectively longer. Design/methodology/approach The study tests the hypotheses through four laboratory experiments. Findings In Studies 1a (N = 88) and 1b (N = 98), the results demonstrate that when participants listen to fast (vs slow) tempo music, they judge temporal distance to
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
20

Faria, João Ricardo. "Profitability, investment, and efficiency wages." Journal of Applied Mathematics and Decision Sciences 2005, no. 4 (2005): 201–11. http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/jamds.2005.201.

Full text
Abstract:
We examine a model that blends the neoclassical theory of investment with an intertemporal efficiency wage model with turnover costs. Investment decisions in capital are associated with the allocation of labor and the determination of efficiency wages. The model relates Tobin's q to efficiency wages and, in particular, to the Solow condition. It provides a general framework to analyze firm's intertemporal choices of capital, labor and efficiency wages.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
21

Livernois, Rebecca. "Regretful Decisions and Climate Change." Philosophy of the Social Sciences 48, no. 2 (2017): 168–91. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0048393117741335.

Full text
Abstract:
Climate change has made pressing the question of why we do little to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. By analogy to the puzzle of the self-torturer, I argue that even if interpersonal and intergenerational conflicts of interest were resolved, we may still end up in a regretful environmental state when we aim to maximize our net benefit derived from polluting activities. This is because a rational agent with transitive preferences making climate change decisions faces incentives to over-pollute. This is caused by the presence of marginal costs that are uninformative of well-being in an uncertai
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
22

Jachimowicz, Jon M., Salah Chafik, Sabeth Munrat, Jaideep C. Prabhu, and Elke U. Weber. "Community trust reduces myopic decisions of low-income individuals." Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 114, no. 21 (2017): 5401–6. http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1617395114.

Full text
Abstract:
Why do the poor make shortsighted choices in decisions that involve delayed payoffs? Foregoing immediate rewards for larger, later rewards requires that decision makers (i) believe future payoffs will occur and (ii) are not forced to take the immediate reward out of financial need. Low-income individuals may be both less likely to believe future payoffs will occur and less able to forego immediate rewards due to higher financial need; they may thus appear to discount the future more heavily. We propose that trust in one’s community—which, unlike generalized trust, we find does not covary with
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
23

JONES, RONALD W. "SPECIFIC FACTORS AND HECKSCHER-OHLIN: AN INTERTEMPORAL BLEND." Singapore Economic Review 52, no. 01 (2007): 1–6. http://dx.doi.org/10.1142/s021759080700252x.

Full text
Abstract:
A blend of the Specific Factors and Heckscher-Ohlin models can be fashioned, making use of some of the ideas in the earlier vintage capital literature. At any given time, production in many sectors reflects past decisions to create sector-specific capital in those sectors. In addition, current capital formation can be focused on one or two best sectors depicted by the Hicksian composite unit-value isoquant. Thus, international trade concentrates current investment decisions and yet allows a variety of goods to be produced.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
24

Kim, Jonghwan. "Do Previous Promotion Awards Affect Current Decisions? Investigation of Intertemporal Correlations of Personnel Decisions." Institute of Management and Economy Research 11, no. 4 (2020): 1–19. http://dx.doi.org/10.32599/apjb.11.4.202012.1.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
25

Rick, Scott, and George Loewenstein. "Intangibility in intertemporal choice." Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 363, no. 1511 (2008): 3813–24. http://dx.doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2008.0150.

Full text
Abstract:
Since the advent of the discounted utility (DU) model, economists have thought about intertemporal choice in very specific terms. DU assumes that people make explicit trade-offs between costs and benefits occurring at different points in time. While this explicit trade-off perspective is simple and tractable, and has stimulated productive research, it does not provide a very realistic representation of a wide range of the most important intertemporal trade-offs that people face in daily life. If one considers the most important and commonly discussed examples of intertemporal choices, a striki
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
26

Reeck, Crystal, Daniel Wall, and Eric J. Johnson. "Search predicts and changes patience in intertemporal choice." Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 114, no. 45 (2017): 11890–95. http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1707040114.

Full text
Abstract:
Intertemporal choice impacts many important outcomes, such as decisions about health, education, wealth, and the environment. However, the psychological processes underlying decisions involving outcomes at different points in time remain unclear, limiting opportunities to intervene and improve people’s patience. This research examines information-search strategies used during intertemporal choice and their impact on decisions. In experiment 1, we demonstrate that search strategies vary substantially across individuals. We subsequently identify two distinct search strategies across individuals.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
27

Juvancic, Luka, and Emil Erjavec. "Intertemporal analysis of employment decisions on agricultural holdings in Slovenia." Agricultural Economics 33, no. 2 (2005): 153–61. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0864.2005.00378.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
28

Paglieri, Fabio. "Social choice for one: On the rationality of intertemporal decisions." Behavioural Processes 127 (June 2016): 97–108. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.beproc.2016.04.011.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
29

Mazzocco, Maurizio, Claudia Ruiz, and Shintaro Yamaguchi. "Labor Supply and Household Dynamics." American Economic Review 104, no. 5 (2014): 354–59. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.5.354.

Full text
Abstract:
Using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, we provide evidence that to understand household decisions and evaluate policies designed to affect individual welfare, it is important to add an intertemporal dimension to the by-now standard static collective models of the household. Specifically, we document that the observed differences in labor supply by gender and marital status do not arise suddenly at the time of marriage, but rather emerge gradually over time. We then propose an intertemporal collective model that has the potential of explaining the observed patterns.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
30

Grace, Kathleen. "The impact of personal income tax rates on the employment decisions of small businesses." Journal of Entrepreneurship and Public Policy 7, no. 1 (2018): 74–104. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/jepp-d-17-00030.

Full text
Abstract:
Purpose Small businesses file taxes in accordance with the personal income tax code because they are considered flow-through entities. Thus, personal income tax reforms directly affect the incentives small business owners face regarding employment and operations. The paper aims to discuss these issues. Design/methodology/approach The authors use the changes in personal income tax rates during the 1993 and 2001-2003 reforms and micro-level data to estimate the effect of statutory tax rate changes on small business employment decisions. Findings The authors add two contributions to the current l
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
31

Stanovich, Keith E. "On the coexistence of cognitivism and intertemporal bargaining." Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28, no. 5 (2005): 661–62. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s0140525x05340118.

Full text
Abstract:
Although Ainslie rejects cognitivism as providing an explanation of willpower, a type of nonhomuncular cognitivism is hiding in his own proposal. The key mental mechanism of aggregating individual decisions (bundled reframings) involves representation and decoupling operations encompassed within the analytic system of dual-process mental architectures.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
32

F. Münte, Thomas, Zheng Ye, Josep Marco-Pallarés, et al. "Dopamine and intertemporal choice in humans." Zeitschrift für Neuropsychologie 29, no. 2 (2018): 81–88. http://dx.doi.org/10.1024/1016-264x/a000218.

Full text
Abstract:
Abstract. The dopamine (DA) system has been implicated in the mediation of cost/benefit evaluations involved in the intertemporal choices between immediate and delayed rewards. This involvement was further investigated in two studies of normal participants that had to decide between a smaller immediate and a larger delayed reward in a series of 27 decisions.In study 1 the dopamine D2/D3 receptor agonist pramipexole or placebo were administered in a double-blind cross-over protocol prior to the decisions. In study 2 the same experiment was conducted in two groups of normal participants that wer
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
33

Miao, Bin, and Songfa Zhong. "Comment on “Risk Preferences Are Not Time Preferences”: Separating Risk and Time Preference." American Economic Review 105, no. 7 (2015): 2272–86. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.20131183.

Full text
Abstract:
Andreoni and Sprenger (2012a,b) observe that utility functions are distinct for risk and time preferences, and show that their findings are consistent with a preference for certainty. We revisit this question in an enriched experimental setting in which subjects make intertemporal decisions under different risk conditions. The observed choice behavior supports a separation between risk attitude and intertemporal substitution rather than a preference for certainty. We further show that several models, including Epstein and Zin (1989); Chew and Epstein (1990); and Halevy (2008) exhibit such a se
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
34

Lindner, Florian, and Julia Rose. "No need for more time: Intertemporal allocation decisions under time pressure." Journal of Economic Psychology 60 (June 2017): 53–70. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.joep.2016.12.004.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
35

Luo, Shan, George Ainslie, and John Monterosso. "The behavioral and neural effect of emotional primes on intertemporal decisions." Social Cognitive and Affective Neuroscience 9, no. 3 (2012): 283–91. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/scan/nss132.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
36

Romero, Marisabel, Adam W. Craig, and Anand Kumar. "Mapping Time: How the Spatial Representation of Time Influences Intertemporal Choices." Journal of Marketing Research 56, no. 4 (2019): 620–36. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0022243719827967.

Full text
Abstract:
Cognitive linguistic studies have found that people perceive time to be intertwined with space. Western consumers, in particular, visualize time on a horizontal spatial axis, with past events on the left and future events on the right. Underexplored, however, is whether and how space-time associations influence future time-related judgments and decisions. For instance, can spatial location cues affect intertemporal decisions? Integrating cognitive linguistics, time psychology, and intertemporal choice, the authors demonstrate across five studies that when choices are displayed horizontally (vs
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
37

Lee, Anthony J., Lisa M. DeBruine, and Benedict C. Jones. "Individual-specific mortality is associated with how individuals evaluate future discounting decisions." Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 285, no. 1880 (2018): 20180304. http://dx.doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2018.0304.

Full text
Abstract:
How organisms discount the value of future rewards is associated with many important outcomes, and may be a central component of theories of life-history. According to life-history theories, prioritizing immediacy is indicative of an accelerated strategy (i.e. reaching reproductive maturity quickly and producing many offspring at the cost of long-term investment). Previous work extrapolating life-history theories to facultative calibration of life-history traits within individuals has theorized that cues to mortality can trigger an accelerated strategy; however, compelling evidence for this hy
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
38

Echenique, Federico. "New Developments in Revealed Preference Theory: Decisions Under Risk, Uncertainty, and Intertemporal Choice." Annual Review of Economics 12, no. 1 (2020): 299–316. http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-082019-110800.

Full text
Abstract:
This article reviews recent developments in revealed preference theory. It discusses the testable implications of theories of choice that are germane to specific economic environments. The focus is on expected utility in risky environments, subjected expected utility and maxmin expected utility in the presence of uncertainty, and exponentially discounted utility for intertemporal choice. The testable implications of these theories for data on choice from classical linear budget sets are described and shown to follow a common thread. The theories all imply an inverse relation between prices and
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
39

Zauberman, Gal, B. Kyu Kim, Selin A. Malkoc, and James R. Bettman. "Discounting Time and Time Discounting: Subjective Time Perception and Intertemporal Preferences." Journal of Marketing Research 46, no. 4 (2009): 543–56. http://dx.doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.46.4.543.

Full text
Abstract:
Consumers often make decisions about outcomes and events that occur over time. This research examines consumers' sensitivity to the prospective duration relevant to their decisions and the implications of such sensitivity for intertemporal trade-offs, especially the degree of present bias (i.e., hyperbolic discounting). The authors show that participants' subjective perceptions of prospective duration are not sufficiently sensitive to changes in objective duration and are nonlinear and concave in objective time, consistent with psychophysical principles. More important, this lack of sensitivit
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
40

Abernethy, Margaret A., Jan Bouwens, and Laurence Van Lent. "The Role of Performance Measures in the Intertemporal Decisions of Business Unit Managers." Contemporary Accounting Research 30, no. 3 (2013): 925–61. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1911-3846.2012.01178.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
41

Wu, Ruohan, and Yuexing Lan. "Production, infrastructure, bribery decisions, and corruption control." Journal of Economic Studies 45, no. 6 (2018): 1106–23. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/jes-03-2017-0078.

Full text
Abstract:
Purpose The purpose of this paper is to study the reasons and decision-making processes of heterogeneous firms’ bribery behavior, and how they will affect an aggregate economy’s development and corruption status. Design/methodology/approach The authors build a dynamic model to study a firm’s joint decision to bribe and invest, and how the decision is determined by its production and infrastructure status. The authors simulate the firm-level decision and development paths, and then build an aggregate economy consisting of heterogeneous firms. The authors then also simulate the development and c
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
42

Wang, Dawei, Leilei Hao, Mengmeng Zhou, et al. "Making decisions for oneself and others: How regulatory focus influences the ‘decision maker role effect’ for intertemporal choices." Personality and Individual Differences 149 (October 2019): 223–30. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.paid.2019.05.034.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
43

Ballard, Ian C., Bokyung Kim, Anthony Liatsis, Gökhan Aydogan, Jonathan D. Cohen, and Samuel M. McClure. "More Is Meaningful: The Magnitude Effect in Intertemporal Choice Depends on Self-Control." Psychological Science 28, no. 10 (2017): 1443–54. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0956797617711455.

Full text
Abstract:
Impulsivity is a variable behavioral trait that depends on numerous factors. For example, increasing the absolute magnitude of available choice options promotes farsighted decisions. We argue that this magnitude effect arises in part from differential exertion of self-control as the perceived importance of the choice increases. First, we demonstrated that frontal executive-control areas were more engaged for more difficult decisions and that this effect was enhanced for high-magnitude rewards. Second, we showed that increased hunger, which is associated with lower self-control, reduced the mag
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
44

Czerwińska-Sabała, Katarzyna. "Intertemporal issues related to anti-tax avoidance clause on the example of the resolutions of the Council for Anti-Tax Avoidance of 18 December 2019." Doradztwo Podatkowe - Biuletyn Instytutu Studiów Podatkowych 3, no. 283 (2020): 18–21. http://dx.doi.org/10.5604/01.3001.0014.0633.

Full text
Abstract:
The article discusses the line of the Council for the Prevention of Tax Avoidance in terms of intertemporal issues of the anti-tax avoidance clause and decisions of the creation moment of the tax benefit. The considerations refer to the Council resolutions No. 3/2019-5/2019 of 18 December 2019 and constitute the part of the first opinions of this institution regarding the application of the art. 119a of the Tax Ordinance Act.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
45

Robson, Arthur J., and Balázs Szentes. "A Biological Theory of Social Discounting." American Economic Review 104, no. 11 (2014): 3481–97. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.11.3481.

Full text
Abstract:
We consider a growth model in which intergenerational transfers are made via stocks of private and public capital. Private capital is the outcome of individuals' private savings while decisions regarding public capital are made collectively. We hypothesize that private saving choices evolve through individual selection while public saving decisions are the result of group selection. The main result of the paper is that the equilibrium rate of return to private capital is at least 2–3 percent more than the rate of return to public capital. In other words, social choices involving intertemporal
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
46

Mainardi, Stefano. "Geological occurrence and economic feasibility in closing decisions by gold mines." South African Journal of Economic and Management Sciences 2, no. 2 (1999): 240–57. http://dx.doi.org/10.4102/sajems.v2i2.2576.

Full text
Abstract:
With successful exploration of deposits often lagging behind mineral extraction, and the international price of gold showing no signs of recovery, mining companies are under pressure to reassess their strategies. The decision whether or not to close a mining activity is the outcome of a process of adapting expectations to a changing economic and geological environment. Part of the literature emphasizes the role of the mineral price and operating costs. However, the extent, pace and intertemporal allocation of metal recovery is in practice determined by a complex interaction of both these with
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
47

Busse, Meghan R., Devin G. Pope, Jaren C. Pope, and Jorge Silva-Risso. "The Psychological Effect of Weather on Car Purchases *." Quarterly Journal of Economics 130, no. 1 (2015): 371–414. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/qje/qju033.

Full text
Abstract:
Abstract When buying durable goods, consumers must forecast how much utility they will derive from future consumption, including consumption in different states of the world. This can be complicated for consumers because making intertemporal evaluations may expose them to a variety of psychological biases such as present bias, projection bias, and salience effects. We investigate whether consumers are affected by such intertemporal biases when they purchase automobiles. Using data for more than 40 million vehicle transactions, we explore the impact of weather on purchasing decisions. We find t
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
48

Dowell, Richard S., and Keith R. McLaren. "An Intertemporal Analysis of the Interdependence between Risk Preference, Retirement, and Work Rate Decisions." Journal of Political Economy 94, no. 3, Part 1 (1986): 667–82. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261395.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
49

GATCHEV, VLADIMIR A., TODD PULVINO, and VEFA TARHAN. "The Interdependent and Intertemporal Nature of Financial Decisions: An Application to Cash Flow Sensitivities." Journal of Finance 65, no. 2 (2010): 725–63. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01549.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
50

Ng, Yew-Kwang. "Do individuals optimize in intertemporal consumption/savings decisions? A liberal method to encourage savings." Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 17, no. 1 (1992): 101–14. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0167-2681(92)90080-u.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!