To see the other types of publications on this topic, follow the link: New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC).

Journal articles on the topic 'New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC)'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the top 50 journal articles for your research on the topic 'New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC).'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Browse journal articles on a wide variety of disciplines and organise your bibliography correctly.

1

Hondroyiannis, George, P. A. V. B. Swamy, and George S. Tavlas. "THE NEW KEYNESIAN PHILLIPS CURVE IN A TIME-VARYING COEFFICIENT ENVIRONMENT: SOME EUROPEAN EVIDENCE." Macroeconomic Dynamics 13, no. 2 (April 2009): 149–66. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1365100508070478.

Full text
Abstract:
We examine whether the importance of lagged inflation in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) may be a result of specification biases. NKPCs are estimated for four countries: France, Germany, Italy, and the United Kingdom. Using time-varying coefficient (TVC) estimation, a procedure that can deal with possible specification biases, we find support for the NKPC model that excludes lagged inflation. Our results indicate a Phillips-curve relationship for the countries considered that does not contain an inertial element.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Satti, Ahsan Ul Haq, Wasim Shahid Malik, and Ghulam Saghir. "New Keynesian Phillips Curve for Pakistan." Pakistan Development Review 46, no. 4II (December 1, 2007): 395–404. http://dx.doi.org/10.30541/v46i4iipp.395-404.

Full text
Abstract:
Recently macroeconomists have moved to a new neo-classical synthesis by integrating Keynesian features like imperfect competition and nominal rigidities with dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the Real Business Cycle Theory with micro foundations and rational expectations, [see, for instance, McCallum and Nelson (1999)]. The standard model comprises of a trinity; consumption and inflation adjustment equations with a monetary authority’s reaction function. One of the pillar of the modelinflation adjustment equation, also known as New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) in the literature, has at least two important features; unlike the traditional Phillips curve the NKPC is forward-looking; and it has been derived from the profit maximising behaviour of the firms in a monopolistically competitive market structure.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Menyhért, B. "Estimating the Hungarian New-Keynesian phillips curve." Acta Oeconomica 58, no. 3 (September 1, 2008): 295–318. http://dx.doi.org/10.1556/aoecon.58.2008.3.3.

Full text
Abstract:
This paper estimates the hybrid New-Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) for Hungary with different techniques. Because of weak instruments, single-equation GMM estimations yield very unreliable results. More robust methods show that basically no statistical inference is possible as to the true specification of the inflation dynamics. However, a more efficient simultaneous-equations method, the full information maximum likelihood (FIML) estimator provides identified parameters. Furthermore, coefficient estimates on the driving variable are positive and significant for the first time, lending much-needed empirical support in favour of the New-Keynesian model. Inflation appears to be determined to an equal extent by past inflation and forward-looking expectations. Structural analysis yields realistic estimates for the frequency of price adjustments and suggests that the dominant price setting behaviour is backward-looking.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Guerrieri, Luca, Christopher Gust, and J. David López-Salido. "International Competition and Inflation: A New Keynesian Perspective." American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2, no. 4 (October 1, 2010): 247–80. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/mac.2.4.247.

Full text
Abstract:
We develop and estimate an open economy New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) in which variable demand elasticities give rise to movements in desired markups in response to changes in competitive pressure from abroad. A parametric restriction yields the standard NKPC under constant elasticity and no role for foreign competition to influence domestic inflation. Foreign competition plays an important role in accounting for the behavior of traded goods price inflation. Foreign competition accounted for more than half of a 4 percentage point decline in domestic goods price inflation in the 1990s. Our results also provide evidence against demand curves with a constant elasticity. (JEL E12, E22, E31, F14, F41)
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Wardhono, Adhitya, M. Abd Nasir, Ciplis Gema Qori’ah, and Yulia Indrawati. "Movement of Inflation and New Keynesian Phillips Curve in ASEAN." Economies 9, no. 1 (March 10, 2021): 34. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/economies9010034.

Full text
Abstract:
The development of the theory of dynamic inflation begins by linking wage inflation and unemployment. In further developments, factor of expectation is classified into inflation model. The study used inflation data is important for ASEAN, because ASEAN is one of the strengths of the international economy. This study analyzes the dynamics of inflation in the ASEAN using framework the New-Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) model. The data used is the quarterly panel data from 5 ASEAN members in the period 2005.QI–2018.QIV. The study of this dynamic inflation applies quarter to quarter inflation data, meaning that the inflation rate is the percentage change in the general price of the current quarter compared to last quarter general price divided by the last quarter. The empirical results are estimated by using the Generalized Method of Moment (GMM), both of the system and first different indicates that the pattern formation of inflation expectations are backward-looking and forward-looking. In addition, the estimated NKPC models show the backward-looking behavior is more dominant than the forward looking. Changes in inflation are not entirely influenced by expectations of inflation in each country. Changes in inflation are also influenced by the output gap, changes in money supply, and exchange rate. Based on the findings of this study, it can be concluded that the NKPC models can explain the dynamics of inflation in each country in the ASEAN region.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Pontiggia, Dario. "Phillips curve and long-run inflation under commitment." Journal of Economic Studies 47, no. 1 (January 1, 2020): 21–35. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/jes-06-2018-0229.

Full text
Abstract:
PurposeThe purpose of this paper is to study the optimal long-run rate of inflation in the presence of a hybrid Phillips curve, which nests a purely backward-looking Phillips curve and the purely forward-looking New Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) as special limiting cases.Design/methodology/approachThis paper derives the long-run rate of inflation in a basic New Keynesian (NK) model, characterized by sticky prices and rule-of-thumb behavior by price setters. The monetary authority possesses commitment and its objective function stems from an approximation to the utility of the representative household.FindingsCommitment solution for the monetary authority leads to steady-state outcomes in which inflation, albeit small, is positive. Rising from zero under the purely forward-looking NKPC, the optimal long-run rate of inflation reaches its maximum under the purely backward-looking Phillips curve. In this case, inflation bias arises, while, under the hybrid Phillips curve, positive long-run inflation is associated with an output gain.Research limitations/implicationsThis paper serves as a clarification against the misperception that log-linearized models take as given the steady-state inflation rate rather than being capable of determining it. Analysis is sensitive to the basic NK setting, with the assumed rule-of-thumb behavior by price setters and price staggering.Originality/valueThe results are the first to quantify the optimal long-run rate of inflation in a fully microfounded model that nests different Phillips curves.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Cogley, Timothy, and Argia M. Sbordone. "Trend Inflation, Indexation, and Inflation Persistence in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve." American Economic Review 98, no. 5 (November 1, 2008): 2101–26. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.98.5.2101.

Full text
Abstract:
Purely forward-looking versions of the New Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) generate too little inflation persistence. Some authors add ad hoc backward-looking terms to address this shortcoming. We hypothesize that inflation persistence results mainly from variation in the long-run trend component of inflation, which we attribute to shifts in monetary policy. We derive a version of the NKPC that incorporates a time-varying inflation trend and examine whether it explains the dynamics of inflation. When drift in trend inflation is taken into account, a purely forward-looking version of the model fits the data well, and there is no need for backward-looking components. (JEL E12, E31, E52)
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Deno Hervino, Aloysius. "A hybrid model of new Keynesian Phillips Curve: An application in Indonesia." Journal of Economics, Business & Accountancy Ventura 18, no. 3 (December 30, 2015): 311. http://dx.doi.org/10.14414/jebav.v18i3.502.

Full text
Abstract:
This study attempts to prove whether inflation dynamics in Indonesia can be explained by the hybrid model of New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC). Output gap variable and dummy variable are also incorporated in this study as the external shock of the increase in fuel oil prices in 2004. By using a steady state model, it can be concluded that inflation dynamics in Indonesia could be explained by the hybrid model of NKPC. The variable of forward looking has significant effect on inflation dynamics, but the variable of inflationary pressure (output gap) has no significant effect on inflation dynamics. In addition, the increase in fuel oil prices in 2004 also gives pressure on the inflation rate, but when interacting with the variable of inflation (backward and forward), it even reduces its pressure on the inflation rate.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Kacemi, Tarek, and Sallahuddin Hassan. "Inflation dynamics analysis in selected MENA countries." Pakistan Journal of Humanities and Social Sciences 6, no. 2 (June 30, 2018): 160–68. http://dx.doi.org/10.52131/pjhss.2018.0602.0040.

Full text
Abstract:
The current paper analyses the new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) in the context of selected MENA countries over the 1990-2016 period. This study has used Pooled Mean Group (PMG) and Fully Modified Ordinary Least Square (FMOLS) estimation methods for the empirical analysis. For the dynamic heterogeneous panels, PMG developed by Pesaran et al. (1999) is the most suitable technique. The outcomes by FMOLS asserted that inflation and unemployment are unrelated in the long run, corroborating the long run Philips Curve theory. While, the empirical outcomes obtained by PMG indicate negative linkage between unemployment and inflation in the long run. Nevertheless, the notion of the tradeoff between the inflation and unemployment that expressed by a short-run Phillips curve is not observed in the selected MENA countries. The findings of this study corroborate the hybrid version of NKPC. Moreover, it establishes of the study suggest that the dynamic inflation can be used as a HNKPC model for understanding the inflation behavior in selected MENA countries.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Salunkhe, Bhavesh, and Anuradha Patnaik. "Inflation Dynamics and Monetary Policy in India: A New Keynesian Phillips Curve Perspective." South Asian Journal of Macroeconomics and Public Finance 8, no. 2 (August 28, 2019): 144–79. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/2277978719861186.

Full text
Abstract:
The present study estimates various specifications of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) models for India over 1996Q2 to 2017Q2 using Consumer Price Index (CPI) and Wholesale Price Index (WPI) inflation, separately. The empirical results suggest that the data support all the specifications of the Phillips curve models based on both the CPI and WPI inflations. However, the backward looking and hybrid models provide robust results for both the inflation indices. While the forward-looking behaviour dominates the CPI inflation trajectory, the backward-looking behaviour greatly influences the trajectory of WPI inflation. Also, a small-to-moderate degree of persistence is evident in both the CPI and WPI inflation. The output gap, which mainly represents the demand side pressures, turns up the major force determining both the CPI and WPI inflations. Besides the output gap, real effective exchange rate (reer), international crude oil price inflation, global non-fuel commodity price inflation and rainfall have a modest impact on the CPI and WPI inflations. JEL Classification: E12, E52, C36, C14
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
11

Schäfer, Benjamin. "The Impact of the Crisis and Unconventional Monetary Policy on European Inflation Dynamics." Review of Economics 69, no. 2 (August 28, 2018): 87–110. http://dx.doi.org/10.1515/roe-2018-0016.

Full text
Abstract:
Abstract This study investigates the impact of the economic crisis in the late 2000s and early 2010s on European inflation dynamics using a hybrid New-Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) during three distinct periods. The pre-crisis period from 1999 through mid-2007, the crisis period until August 2012, and finally the “Whatever-It-Takes”-period after the remark by ECB president Mario Draghi. The structural hybrid NKPC is estimated for six countries of the Euro area (Germany, France, Italy, Spain, The Netherlands and Austria) and for each of the three periods. The crisis and the subsequent reaction of the ECB both seem to have had a profound impact on the dynamics, as estimated parameters differ markedly between the periods. A discussion and interpretation of the results is provided.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
12

Bratsiotis, George J., and Wayne A. Robinson. "UNIT TOTAL COSTS: AN ALTERNATIVE MARGINAL COST PROXY FOR INFLATION DYNAMICS." Macroeconomic Dynamics 20, no. 7 (September 28, 2015): 1826–49. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1365100515000140.

Full text
Abstract:
The New Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) driven byunit labor costshas been criticized for failing to match inflation dynamics and for failing to explain the duration of price contracts. This paper extends recent attempts in the literature to improve the fit of the NKPC, by introducing a fuller marginal cost proxy,unit total costs, that is derived from bothlaborandnonlabor unit costs; the latter include capital-related costs and production taxes. Borrowing costs are examined separately, as in the cost channel literature.Unit total costsare shown to improve the fit of the short-run variation in inflation and strengthen the empirical support for the role of expectations-based inflation persistence. They also imply a duration of fixed nominal contracts that is closer to those suggested by firm-level surveys. Thecost channelbecomes relatively less important whenunit total costs, rather thanunit labor costs, are used as a marginal cost proxy.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
13

Jha, Raghbendra, and Varsha S. Kulkarni. "Inflation, its volatility and the inflation-growth tradeoff in India." International Journal of Emerging Markets 10, no. 3 (July 20, 2015): 350–61. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/ijoem-09-2013-0145.

Full text
Abstract:
Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to amend the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) model to include inflation volatility. It provides results on the determinants of inflation volatility and expected inflation volatility for ordinary least squares and autoregressive distributed lags (1,1) models and for change in inflation volatility and change in expected inflation volatility using error correction mechanism (ECM) models. Output gap affects change in expected inflation volatility alone (in the ECM model) and not in the other models. Major determinants of inflation volatility and expected inflation volatility are identified. To the best of the authors knowledge this is the first paper to augment the NKPC to include inflation volatility. Design/methodology/approach – Recent analysis has indicated the importance of inflation volatility for the monetary transmission mechanism in India (Kapur and Behera, 2012). In the analysis of such monetary policy mechanisms the NKPC has proved to be a useful tool. Thus Patra and Ray (2010) for India and Brissimis and Magginas (2008) for the USA find considerable support for the standard NKPC. The purpose of this paper is to synthesize and integrate these two models by extending the standard NKPC framework to include inflation volatility and test its significance for the case of India. Findings – In the case of inflation volatility output gap, lagged output gap and lagged inflation volatility are all insignificant. The level of inflation has a negative significant impact whereas the level of expected inflation has a positive and significant impact. In the case of expected inflation volatility lagged output gap has a negative and significant impact, the price level has a positive and significant impact whereas expected price has a negative and weakly significant impact. ECM reveals change in inflation variability falls significantly with lagged inflation volatility and lagged inflation and less significantly with change in expected inflation. It rises with lagged expected inflation although the coefficient is only weakly significant. Lagged output gap and change in output gap are insignificant. Originality/value – This paper makes two original contributions. First, it extends the New Keynesian framework to include inflation volatility. Second, it estimates this model for India. To the best of the authors knowledge this is the first paper to make these contributions.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
14

Boug, Pål, Ådne Cappelen, and Anders Rygh Swensen. "The new Keynesian Phillips curve revisited." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34, no. 5 (May 2010): 858–74. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2010.01.001.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
15

Malikane, Christopher. "A new Keynesian triangle Phillips curve." Economic Modelling 43 (December 2014): 247–55. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.08.010.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
16

Nason, James M., and Gregor W. Smith. "Identifying the new Keynesian Phillips curve." Journal of Applied Econometrics 23, no. 5 (August 2008): 525–51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/jae.1011.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
17

Roberts, John M. "New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 27, no. 4 (November 1995): 975. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2077783.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
18

Scheufele, Rolf. "Evaluating the German (New Keynesian) Phillips curve." North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21, no. 2 (August 2010): 145–64. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2009.06.001.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
19

Kuester, Keith, Gernot J. Müller, and Sarah Stölting. "Is the New Keynesian Phillips curve flat?" Economics Letters 103, no. 1 (April 2009): 39–41. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2009.01.024.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
20

Rudd, Jeremy, and Karl Whelan. "New tests of the new-Keynesian Phillips curve." Journal of Monetary Economics 52, no. 6 (September 2005): 1167–81. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.08.006.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
21

Rudd, Jeremy Bay, and Karl Whelan. "New Tests of the New-Keynesian Phillips Curve." Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2001, no. 30 (2001): 1–30. http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/feds.2001.30.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
22

Maichal, Maichal. "KURVA PHILLIPS DI INDONESIA." Jurnal Ekonomi Pembangunan: Kajian Masalah Ekonomi dan Pembangunan 13, no. 2 (December 1, 2012): 183. http://dx.doi.org/10.23917/jep.v13i2.178.

Full text
Abstract:
This paper aims to analyze the existence of the Philips curve in the Indonesian economy, 2000Q1-2010Q3. The results obtained by using OLS method shows that the expectations augmented Philips curve and the New Keynesian Philips curve models cannot give a clear results of Philips curve existence in the Idonesia economy. Shocks variable such as percentage change of exchange rates and crude oil prices provide a very small effect on the inflation rate in Indonesia. Furthermore, the results obtained by using GMM method on the hybrid model of the New Keynesian Philips curve shows that the Philips curve exists in the Indonesian economy.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
23

Orland, Andreas, and Michael W. M. Roos. "The New Keynesian Phillips curve with myopic agents." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, no. 11 (November 2013): 2270–86. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2013.05.015.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
24

Mazumder, Sandeep. "European Inflation and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve." Southern Economic Journal 79, no. 2 (October 2012): 322–49. http://dx.doi.org/10.4284/0038-4038-2011.149.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
25

Chadha, Jagjit S., and Charles Nolan. "Output, Inflation and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve." International Review of Applied Economics 18, no. 3 (July 2004): 271–87. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/0269217042000227060.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
26

LUBIK, THOMAS A., and WING LEONG TEO. "Deep Habits in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46, no. 1 (January 20, 2014): 79–114. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jmcb.12098.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
27

Malikane, Christopher, and Tshepo Mokoka. "The new Keynesian Phillips curve: endogeneity and misspecification." Applied Economics 46, no. 25 (May 28, 2014): 3082–89. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2014.922672.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
28

Bardsen, Gunnar, Eilev S. Jansen, and Ragnar Nymoen. "Econometric Evaluation of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve*." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 66, s1 (September 2004): 671–86. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2004.00097.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
29

Ahrens, Steffen, and Stephen Sacht. "Estimating a high-frequency New-Keynesian Phillips curve." Empirical Economics 46, no. 2 (March 31, 2013): 607–28. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0684-7.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
30

Chin, Kuo-Hsuan. "New Keynesian Phillips Curve with time-varying parameters." Empirical Economics 57, no. 6 (July 30, 2018): 1869–89. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1536-2.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
31

Ayinde, Ramat Adedoyin, Benedict Akanegbu, and Gylych Jelilov. "Estimation of New Keynesian Phillips Curve for Nigeria." Journal of Developing Areas 55, no. 3 (2021): 149–58. http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/jda.2021.0057.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
32

Lanne, Markku, and Jani Luoto. "Autoregression-based estimation of the new Keynesian Phillips curve." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, no. 3 (March 2013): 561–70. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2012.09.008.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
33

Born, Benjamin, and Johannes Pfeifer. "THE NEW KEYNESIAN WAGE PHILLIPS CURVE: CALVO VS. ROTEMBERG." Macroeconomic Dynamics 24, no. 5 (November 27, 2018): 1017–41. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1365100518000615.

Full text
Abstract:
We systematically evaluate how to translate a Calvo wage duration into an implied Rotemberg wage adjustment cost parameter in medium-scale New Keynesian DSGE models by making use of the well-known equivalence of the two setups at first order. We consider a wide range of felicity functions and show that the assumed household insurance scheme and the presence of labor taxation greatly matter for this mapping, giving rise to differences of up to one order of magnitude. Our results account for the inclusion of wage indexing, habit formation in consumption, and the presence of fixed costs in production. We also investigate the conditional and unconditional welfare implications of the wage-setting schemes under efficient and distorted steady states.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
34

Piao, Jishi, and Sangyong Joo. "Estimating Open Economy New Keynesian Phillips Curve for Korea." Asian Economic Journal 28, no. 3 (September 2014): 239–58. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/asej.12035.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
35

Zhang, Chengsi, Denise R. Osborn, and Dong Heon Kim. "Observed Inflation Forecasts and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 71, no. 3 (June 2009): 375–98. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2009.00544.x.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
36

Wong, Chin-Yoong, and Yoke-Kee Eng. "Vertically globalized production structure in New Keynesian Phillips curve." North American Journal of Economics and Finance 21, no. 2 (August 2010): 198–216. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.najef.2009.03.004.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
37

Kim, Bae-Geun. "Does the New Keynesian Phillips curve need countercyclical markups?" Economic Modelling 63 (June 2017): 262–82. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2017.02.017.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
38

Abbas, Syed Kanwar, and Pasquale M. Sgro. "New Keynesian Phillips Curve and inflation dynamics in Australia." Economic Modelling 28, no. 4 (July 2011): 2022–33. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2011.04.002.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
39

Hyder, Kalim, and Stephen G. Hall. "Estimates of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve for Pakistan." Empirical Economics 59, no. 2 (March 16, 2019): 871–86. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01659-8.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
40

Matheron, Julien, and Tristan-Pierre Maury. "Supply-side refinements and the New Keynesian Phillips Curve." Economics Letters 82, no. 3 (March 2004): 391–96. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2003.09.018.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
41

Carriero, Andrea. "A simple test of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve." Economics Letters 100, no. 2 (August 2008): 241–44. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2008.02.012.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
42

Lubik, Thomas A., and Wing Leong Teo. "Inventories, inflation dynamics and the New Keynesian Phillips curve." European Economic Review 56, no. 3 (April 2012): 327–46. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2011.10.002.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
43

Liu, Dandan. "Learning and Estimation of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Models." Southern Economic Journal 78, no. 2 (October 2011): 382–96. http://dx.doi.org/10.4284/0038-4038-78.2.382.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
44

Dadam and Viegi. "Estimating a New Keynesian Wage Phillips Curve for South Africa." Journal of Development Perspectives 3, no. 1-2 (2019): 137. http://dx.doi.org/10.5325/jdevepers.3.1-2.0137.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
45

Bjørnstad, Roger, and Ragnar Nymoen. "The New Keynesian Phillips Curve Tested on OECD Panel Data." Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 2, no. 2008-23 (2008): 1. http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2008-23.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
46

Rondina, Francesca. "Estimating Unobservable Inflation Expectations in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve." Econometrics 6, no. 1 (February 5, 2018): 6. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/econometrics6010006.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
47

Etro, Federico, and Lorenza Rossi. "New-Keynesian Phillips curve with Bertrand competition and endogenous entry." Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 51 (February 2015): 318–40. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2014.10.009.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
48

Batini, Nicoletta, Brian Jackson, and Stephen Nickell. "An open-economy new Keynesian Phillips curve for the U.K." Journal of Monetary Economics 52, no. 6 (September 2005): 1061–71. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.08.003.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
49

Razin, Assaf, and Chi-Wa Yuen. "The ‘New Keynesian’ Phillips curve: closed economy versus open economy." Economics Letters 75, no. 1 (March 2002): 1–9. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s0165-1765(01)00588-2.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
50

Fanelli, Luca. "Evaluating the New Keynesian Phillips Curve under VAR-based Learning." Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 2, no. 2008-33 (2008): 1. http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2008-33.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!

To the bibliography