Academic literature on the topic 'Revenues sharing'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the lists of relevant articles, books, theses, conference reports, and other scholarly sources on the topic 'Revenues sharing.'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Journal articles on the topic "Revenues sharing"

1

Heese, H. Sebastian, and Eda Kemahlioglu-Ziya. "Enabling Opportunism: Revenue Sharing when Sales Revenues are Unobservable." Production and Operations Management 23, no. 9 (November 6, 2013): 1634–45. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/poms.12163.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Bergantiños, Gustavo, and Juan D. Moreno-Ternero. "Sharing the Revenues from Broadcasting Sport Events." Management Science 66, no. 6 (June 2020): 2417–31. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2019.3313.

Full text
Abstract:
We study the problem of sharing the revenues from broadcasting sport league events among participating teams. We provide direct, axiomatic, and game-theoretical foundations for two focal rules: the equal-split rule and concede-and-divide. The former allocates the revenues generated from broadcasting each game equally among the participating teams in the game. The latter concedes each team the revenues from its fan base and divides equally the residual. We also provide an application studying the case of sharing the revenue from broadcasting games in La Liga, the Spanish Football League. We show that hybrid schemes, combining our rules with lower bounds and performance measures, yield close outcomes to the current allocation being implemented by the Spanish National Professional Football League Association. This paper was accepted by Manel Baucells, decision analysis.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Khakim, Luqman, Iwan Hermawan, Achmad Solechan, and VS Tripriyo PS. "POTENSI FISKAL TERHADAP PERTUMBUHAN EKONOMI DAN KESEJAHTERAAN MASYARAKAT." Jurnal Ekonomi Pembangunan: Kajian Masalah Ekonomi dan Pembangunan 12, no. 2 (December 1, 2011): 281. http://dx.doi.org/10.23917/jep.v12i2.199.

Full text
Abstract:
This research objectives are first, to determine the influence of potential fiscal (local revenue, general allocation fund, sharing fund, and other official local revenues) to local economic growth. Second, to study potential fiscal impact and local economic growth to its society welfare. The study took all population as it samples (116 cities in Java), ie: local budget realization of all cities in Java from 2007-2009 and uses panel data. Lisrel 8.54 is employed to analyze to form Structural Equation Modeling. The result shows that first, local revenues and sharing fund have positive influence to economic growth, while general allocation fund and other local revenues influence negatively to economic growth. Second, local revenues, general allocation fund and sharing fund have positive impact on local society welfare, while the other local revenues have no significant impact on it.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

GROOM, ROSEMARY, and STEPHEN HARRIS. "Conservation on community lands: the importance of equitable revenue sharing." Environmental Conservation 35, no. 3 (August 28, 2008): 242–51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s037689290800489x.

Full text
Abstract:
SUMMARYAttempts to establish local support for wildlife and conservation through the sharing of revenues and empowerment of local communities to manage their wildlife have proliferated over the past two decades. Data from two neighbouring Maasai group ranches in the wildlife dispersal area of Amboseli and Tsavo National Parks (Kenya) indicated one ranch generated considerable wildlife revenues from a tourist operation and community trust while the other received no direct benefits from wildlife. The overall attitude to wildlife on the ranch with wildlife revenues was significantly more positive, but attitudes within the ranch varied significantly, depending on both costs from wildlife and perception of the distribution of wildlife revenues. Ordinal logistic regression analyses showed that it was not the amount of revenue received or the scale of costs from wildlife which determined people's attitudes, but simply the presence or absence of wildlife benefits. The importance of addressing inequitable distribution of benefits is emphasized.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Rockerbie, Duane. "Free Agent Auctions and Revenue Sharing: A Simple Exposition." Journal of Sport Management 23, no. 1 (January 2009): 87–98. http://dx.doi.org/10.1123/jsm.23.1.87.

Full text
Abstract:
This article uses a simple approach to address the issue of how revenue sharing in professional sports leagues can affect the allocation of free agent players to teams. To affect the allocation of free agents, the imposition of revenue sharing must alter the ranking of bidding teams in terms of maximum salary offers. Two types of revenue sharing systems are considered: traditional gate revenue sharing and pooled revenue sharing. The article suggests that team rankings for ability to pay are not affected by pooled revenue sharing, however the distribution of player salaries will be affected asymmetrically. Traditional gate revenue sharing can alter the ability to pay rankings for teams, depending upon playing schedules and the closeness of revenues between closely ranked teams. Revenue data for two professional sports leagues provide evidence in favor of the model predictions.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Song, Xu. "Journey to the East: A Review of Hollywood’s Film Localization Efforts for China’s Film Market." International Journal of English and Cultural Studies 2, no. 1 (December 11, 2018): 1. http://dx.doi.org/10.11114/ijecs.v2i1.3872.

Full text
Abstract:
The film market of China has been growing rapidly and is now the world’s second largest film market. Hollywood studios have been sending transnational films to China to receive additional revenues. This research investigates the three channels (i.e., flat-rate buyouts, co-productions, and revenue-sharing titles) through which Hollywood studios can enter their films in China’s film market and reviews the China-focused localization efforts that Hollywood studios have made to appeal to China. The review findings show that exporting Hollywood films to China as revenue-sharing titles has become the favorite approach for major Hollywood studios to gain additional revenues. To improve revenue-sharing films’ box-office performance, localization efforts of Hollywood studios are executed throughout a film’s theatrical life cycle, from a film’s planning and production stages to its distribution, promotion, and exhibition stages. Implications and suggestions as to how Hollywood studios can further utilize film localization efforts to enhance box-office success in China are also discussed in the present study.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Rockerbie, Duane, and Stephen Easton. "Revenue Sharing in Major League Baseball: The Moments That Meant so Much." International Journal of Financial Studies 6, no. 3 (August 6, 2018): 71. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6030071.

Full text
Abstract:
Revenue sharing is a common league policy in professional sports leagues. Several motivations for revenue sharing have been explored in the literature, including supporting small market teams, affecting league parity, suppressing player salaries, and improving team profitability. We investigate a different motivation. Risk-averse team owners, through their commissioner, are able to increase their utility by using revenue sharing to affect higher order moments of the revenue distribution. In particular, it may reduce the variance and kurtosis, as well as affecting the skewness of the league distribution of team local revenues. We first determine the extent to which revenue sharing affects these moments in theory, then we quantify the effects on utility for Major League Baseball over the period 2002–2013. Our results suggest that revenue sharing produced significant utility gains at little cost, which enhanced the positive effects noted by other studies.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Hikmah, Ainul, and Nahariah Nahariah. "Analisis Nisbah Bagi Hasil Pembiayaan Mudharabah pada Bank Syariah Mandiri KCP Sengkang." Jurnal Ilmiah Al-Tsarwah 2, no. 2 (July 20, 2019): 140–54. http://dx.doi.org/10.30863/al-tsarwah.v2i2.294.

Full text
Abstract:
The purpose of this research is to understand the meaning of revenue sharing, the method of calculating revenue sharing and the profit sharing advantage on mudharabah financing in independent Islamic banks. The results of the study show that Revenue Sharing is a profit sharing system that is calculated from the total revenue of fund management without being reduced by the cost of managing funds. So if the bank and the customer use the mudharabah scheme in carrying out working capital financing, if the business is profitable, then it must be divided based on the profit sharing portion. The advantages of mudharabah financing sharing ratio in Bank Syariah Mandiri Sengkang KCP is to be able to increase investment in third party funds on Islamic banks because if the bank uses a profit sharing calculation system based on revenue sharing where profit sharing will be distributed from total revenues before deducting with costs, the likelihood that there will be a profit sharing rate that will be received by the owner of the fund will be greater than the prevailing market interest rate.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Kartawinata, Budi Rustandi, Candra Wijayangka, and Muhammad Hasan Rabbani. "Analisis Perbedaan Revenue Bunga Bank Konvensional Dengan Bagi Hasil Bank Syariah (Studi PT Bank Maybank Tbk dan PT Bank BRI Syariah Tbk)." eCo-Buss 1, no. 3 (April 26, 2019): 196–202. http://dx.doi.org/10.32877/eb.v1i3.65.

Full text
Abstract:
Financial institutions divided into two, conventional banking and sharia banking. The fundamental thing that distinguishes between conventional and sharia financial institutions lies in the return and profit sharing provided by customers to financial institutions and / or provided by financial institutions to customers (Muhamad, 2014). Operational activities of sharia banks use the Profit Sharing Principle. This research was conducted in order to find out Revenues comparison between interest given by Bank Maybank with Profit Sharing given by Bank BRI Syariah. The purpose of this study is to find out whether there is a difference between the ratio of Revenue and analyze which greater revenue gave from Bank Maybank Interest to Profit Sharing gave from Bank BRI Syariah. The research method used in this research is qualitative method, and data collection technique using secondary data which researcher use data of financial report at bank Maybank and BRI Syariah for saving from 2012-2016. Data analysis technique used in this study is by using T test, which divided into three, normality test, homogeneity test and independent test. The revenues comparison between conventional bank interests were different to profit sharing given by sharia bank. Profit sharing given by Syariah Bank is greater because Conventional Bank uses tier system while Syariah Bank does not
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Roy, Juliansyah, and Dio Caisar Darma. "Fiscal Degree Performance in Samarinda City: Budget Year of 2013-2017." Journal of Business and Economics 10, no. 3 (March 20, 2019): 227–43. http://dx.doi.org/10.15341/jbe(2155-7950)/03.10.2019/005.

Full text
Abstract:
The aim to be achieved in the study is to analyze and identify the degree of fiscal decentralization in the City of Samarinda during 2013-2017. This type of research is quantitative and the data source used is secondary data. The data is based on time series during budget year of 2013-2017, which was compiled through the publication of the Regional Revenue Agency and Central Bureau of Statistics Samarinda City. The analytical tool used is Degree of Fiscal Decentralization.Simple conclusions that can be obtained based on the analytical tool, namely: (1) The average ratio of Regional Original Income to Regional Revenues is 3.44% (very less); (2) The average ratio of Tax Sharing and Non Tax/Natural Resources Sharing to Regional Revenues is 39.69% (sufficient); (3) The average ratio of Balanced Budget to Regional Revenues is 64.51% (very good); (4) The average ratio of Regional Original Income to Regional Expenditures is 11.94% (less); (5) The average ratio of Regional Original Income to Capital Expenditures is 42.75% (good); and (6) The average ratio of Tax Sharing, Non Tax/Natural Resources Sharing, and Regional Original Income to Regional Expenditure is 47.20% (good).
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
More sources

Dissertations / Theses on the topic "Revenues sharing"

1

Michel, Alyona. "Airline alliance revenue management : improving joint revenues through partner sharing of flight leg opportunity costs." Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 2012. http://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/78147.

Full text
Abstract:
Thesis (S.M. in Transportation)--Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Dept. of Civil and Environmental Engineering, 2012.
Cataloged from PDF version of thesis.
Includes bibliographical references (p. 125-128).
Airlines participating in alliances offer code share itineraries (with flight segments operated by different partners) to expand the range of origin-destination combinations offered to passengers, thus increasing market share at little cost. The presence of code share flights presents a problem for airline revenue management (RM) systems, which aim to maximize revenues in an airline's network by determining which booking requests are accepted. Because partners do not jointly optimize revenues on code share flights, alliance revenue gains from implementing advanced RM methods may be lower than an individual airline's gains. This thesis examines seat availability control methods that alliance partners can adopt to improve the total revenues of the alliance without formally merging. Partners share information about the opportunity costs to their network, called "bid prices", of selling a seat on their own flight leg, a mechanism termed bid price sharing (BPS). Results show that BPS methods often improve revenues and work best for networks with certain characteristics and partners with similar RM systems that exchange recently calculated bid prices as often as possible. Gains are typically only achieved if both alliance partners participate in the code share availability decision (called dual control) rather than one partner only, but implementation of dual control is more difficult for airlines in practice. In the best case scenario, gains of up to .40% where achieved, which can translate into $120 million per year for the largest airlines. In our simulations, BPS with dual control and frequent bid price calculation and exchange was the only method that produced consistently positive revenue gains in all the scenarios tested. Therefore, alliance airlines must consider the trade off between revenue gains and implementation difficulties of more frequent bid price exchange or dual control.
by Alyona Michel.
S.M.in Transportation
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Nyborg, Anne Mette. "Income characterization and the sharing of global tax revenues in the context of electronic commerce." Thesis, University of British Columbia, 2007. http://hdl.handle.net/2429/31910.

Full text
Abstract:
The question of characterizing income by its source in the context of electronic commerce has brought forward problematic issues in the international taxation regime. It has presented prominent scholars, administrators and judges with what have sometimes seemed intractable difficulties. Characterization and geographic source difficulties are linked to the lack of international uniformity in the characterization of income from computer software transactions, which expose taxpayers to potentially arbitrary characterization outcomes. Characterization outcomes also affect the global sharing of tax revenues collected from international transactions as the taxation in a particular country is linked to the character of the income. The current international tax system furthermore brings forward problems of equity and the inequalities between developed and developing countries in sharing international tax revenues arising from electronic commerce transactions. In this thesis I analyze the international tax rules currently applied to electronic commerce transactions. I explore the underlying rationale for characterizing income by its source and the international uniformity in the area. I review the international guidance for the application of traditional rules to electronic commerce transactions and examine the international uniformity for the characterization. Moreover, I review the theoretical foundation for the taxation of international income and analyze the imbalance in sharing the global tax base under the current rules. This reveals, that the underlying rationale for income characterization has no convincing support for the continued distinction. The application of traditional rules and concepts reveals uncertainties and complications and there is no absolute international uniformity. Ultimately, the theoretical basis for taxing international income appears to suffer a disconnect and today's system furthermore fails to ensure a fair sharing of the global tax base.
Law, Peter A. Allard School of
Graduate
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Hu, Wan-ting Banerjee Avijit Kim Seung-Lae. "Supply chain coordination contracts with free replacement warranty /." Philadelphia, Pa. : Drexel University, 2008. http://hdl.handle.net/1860/2830.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Adams, Jason. "The NBA's Revenue Sharing Scorecard: Determining Success for Small-Market Franchises." Thesis, Boston College, 2010. http://hdl.handle.net/2345/1569.

Full text
Abstract:
Thesis advisor: Christopher Maxwell
Although there is extensive theoretical and empirical literature discussing the impact of revenue sharing agreements on competitive balance in professional sports leagues, there has been little work done to improve the structure of current agreements which are designed to improve competitive balance. This paper focuses on the National Basketball Association (NBA) and the current revenue sharing agreements it has in place. This paper both evaluates franchises’ efforts in earning revenue sharing payments and offers alternative metrics designed to accomplish the goals of league-wide profitability and competitive balance
Thesis (BA) — Boston College, 2010
Submitted to: Boston College. College of Arts and Sciences
Discipline: Economics Honors Program
Discipline: Economics
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Chen, Lihua. "Fair Sharing of Costs and Revenue through Transfer Pricing in Supply Chains with Stochastic Demand." Kent State University / OhioLINK, 2011. http://rave.ohiolink.edu/etdc/view?acc_num=kent1311019238.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Cox, Adam John. "An economic analysis of spectator demand, club performance, and revenue sharing in English Premier League football." Thesis, University of Portsmouth, 2016. https://researchportal.port.ac.uk/portal/en/theses/an-economic-analysis-of-spectator-demand-club-performance-and-revenue-sharing-in-english-premier-league-football(be4c9045-e4cb-4d75-96b7-2ebe80c160b8).html.

Full text
Abstract:
Since its creation in 1992, the Premier League has sold exclusive media rights for live football matches to broadcasters on behalf of member clubs. The collective selling method removes any price competition between the clubs, whom would otherwise compete against each other to sell rights to their matches (commonly seen in other European Leagues). A key issue with monopoly power is that the Premier League could distort the market for its product or abuse its dominant position in the market as the sole seller of the rights (contrary to Article 101 and 102 of the Treaty of the European Union). In defence, the Premier League argued that matches broadcast live on television can be considered as a substitute for watching at the stadium. A Competition Commission investigation concluded that the potential benefits of collective selling arrangements are for the redistribution of revenue to promote solidarity at all levels of football. After some amendments to the auction process, collective selling continues. Contributing to the applied industrial economics literature, this thesis examines the key arguments for using collective selling methods in the Premier League. Results from empirical economic analysis find firstly, that there is no evidence to suggest a negative impact on match day revenue from live broadcasting and the revenues from rights sales heavily outweigh such an impact. Secondly, that sharing revenue between clubs will only enhance solidarity (competitive balance) if the amount shared is much larger than at present, however, a greater uncertainty of match outcome reduces demand for spectating at the stadium whilst increasing demand for television viewing. Finally, the impact of investment in talent is far greater for weaker teams whilst participating in the Champions League and Europa League has no impact on domestic league performance. This thesis concludes that the Premier League should offer a greater number of rights to broadcast matches and should increase the amount of revenue shared (including revenues from European Competitions) in order to increase competitive balance. This would increase the number of television viewers for live football broadcasts but would likely reduce the numbers of fans spectating at the stadium.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Harmer, Camille. "The Effects of Fluctuations in Federal Revenue Sharing Payments Made to Rural Counties on School District Budgets." DigitalCommons@USU, 2019. https://digitalcommons.usu.edu/etd/7644.

Full text
Abstract:
Federal revenue sharing programs aim to make up lost tax revenue to counties that contain federal land, as counties do not receive any property tax revenue from publicly owned lands. This may have a significant impact on rural school districts with a limited tax base, as most funding for public education comes from property tax revenue. My analysis seeks to determine the full impact of certain federal revenue sharing payments (paid out by the U.S. Forest Service) on school districts in counties that contain U.S. Forest Service land. My analysis shows that the payments have little impact on school district budgets, indicating that states likely smooth for variations in the U.S. Forest Service payments.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Petersen, Hans-Georg. "Integration, decentralization, taxation, and revenue sharing : good governance, sustainable fiscal policy and poverty reduction as peace-keeping strategies." Universität Potsdam, 2008. http://opus.kobv.de/ubp/volltexte/2008/2736/.

Full text
Abstract:
The paper tries to shed some light on the problems of centralization and decentralization within an economic union and the federal member states. Integration and decentralization are not opposite policy strategies but both meaningful if the single public goods and services supplies are analyzed in more detail. Both strategies doubtlessly have advantages, which can be realized if the manifold possibilities are combined in an efficient approach of good governance. Best practice approaches in inter- or supra-national integration, fiscal federalism and taxation do exist and have to be successfully implemented. Obviously such a modern fiscal policy has to be accompanied by an appropriate monetary policy, which in an economic union has to be carried out by an independent central bank as one of the necessary countervailing powers in a democratic setting. A modern fiscal policy strategy efficiently controls budget deficits, which naturally have to be limited to finance reliable public investments. Such strategy has to be safeguarded through modern methods of budgeting and fiscal planning. Modern public management with a clear code of conduct for the government officials ensures corruption free administration.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Castilho, Fábio Roberto Corrêa. "Federalismo fiscal e repartição do ICMS: o critério do valor adicionado." Universidade de São Paulo, 2014. http://www.teses.usp.br/teses/disponiveis/2/2133/tde-12122014-100106/.

Full text
Abstract:
O trabalho concentra-se sobre o critério do valor adicionado fiscal na repartição do ICMS, com o objetivo de verificar sua adequação como mecanismo de provisão de recursos financeiros a Municípios, no contexto do federalismo fiscal brasileiro. Mediante análise teórica, de dados de distribuição e legislação referente à repartição e ao ICMS, identificamos que o valor adicionado fiscal é gerador de enormes desigualdades de tratamento entre Municípios de porte equivalente e de oscilações brutais de valores de transferência de um para outro ano, mas, sobretudo, que é juridicamente inadequado à multiplicidade de locais de ocorrência de fatos geradores e a heterogeneidade do imposto que pretende repartir. Não atinge, assim, o propósito de medir a adição de valor em um território, nem o de conferir aos Municípios receitas em montante similar ao potencial de arrecadação de um imposto sobre valor adicionado municipal depurado dos efeitos de imunidades, isenções, diferimentos e substituições tributárias, que justificou sua criação. A permanência da utilização do critério do valor adicionado por décadas é apontada no trabalho como resultante de acomodações e ajustes institucionais, característicos de dependência de trajetória (path dependence), que, desrespeitando os limites jurídicos de regulamentação, disfarçam a inadequação do critério e perpetuam as desigualdades e instabilidades dele advindas. Justifica-se, assim, que atenções sejam voltadas à análise de alternativas à repartição do ICMS por outros meios que não o VAF e o aperfeiçoamento de seus mecanismos de regulação, caso permaneça sendo utilizado.
The Added Value Criteria (VAF) is used in Brazil for purposes of ICMS (A State tax on circulation of goods, communication and interstate and intercity transportation services) revenue sharing to cities. The data on how the VAT based tax sharing occurs shows that VAT is a source of inequalities in resource distribution to cities of equivalent population and oscillations in the amounts received by a given city along the years. Moreover and as the central hypothesis of this thesis, VAF, as defined in Brazilian legislation, is not suitable to the complexity of situations and places of occurrence of ICMS taxable events nor to the effects of ICMS on prices, being, thus, unable to measure the value added in each city territory and to protect the revenue sharing from the effects of ICMS exemptions, constitutional immunities, deferrals and tax substitutions. Being so, the VAT regulations, do not recreate the potential of a municipal VAT, falling short in accomplishing the purposes it was created for. In spite of its defects, VAT remains in use decades after its creation as a result of accommodations and institutional adjustments that can be explained by a path dependence trajectory that was, and still, is able to disguise its chronic inadequacies and to perpetuate the inequalities and instabilities arising out of such distribution criteria. Our conclusions on VAF justify the study of other alternatives for the ICMS revenue sharing, as well as attempts to improve the quality of VAT regulations.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Lintner, Markus. "Die verfassungsrechtlichen Grenzen des horizontalen Länderfinanzausgleichs nach Art. 107 Abs. 2 GG /." Frankfurt am Main [u.a.] : Lang, 2004. http://www.gbv.de/dms/spk/sbb/recht/toc/389231649.pdf.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
More sources

Books on the topic "Revenues sharing"

1

Slack, N. E. Intermunicipal cooperation: Sharing of expenditures & revenues. Toronto: Intergovernmental Committee on Urban & Regional Research, 1997.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

McCleary, W. A. Earmarking government revenues in Colombia. Washington, D.C. (1818 H St., NW, Washington 20433): World Bank, 1990.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Florida. Legislature. Senate. Committee on Government Efficiency Appropriations. State revenues shared with local governments, a state-by-state comparison. [Tallahassee, Fla.]: The Committee, 2006.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Florida. Legislature. Legislative Committee on Intergovernmental Relations. State revenue sharing with local governments: With particular emphasis on local government revenues derived from cigarette taxes. [Tallahassee, Fla.]: The Committee, 1999.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

O'Cleireacain, Carol. The orphaned capital: Adopting the right revenues for the District of Columbia. Washington, D.C: Brookings Institution Press, 1997.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

From revenue sharing to deficit sharing: General revenue sharing and cities. Washington, D.C: Georgetown University Press, 1998.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

United States. Congress. Senate. Committee on Energy and Natural Resources. Outer continental shelf revenues: Hearing before the Committee on Energy and Natural Resources, United States Senate, Ninety-ninth Congress, first session, on the distribution of outer continental shelf section 8(g) revenues in response to instructions from the budget resolution, September 24, 1985. Washington: U.S. G.P.O., 1986.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

United States. Congress. Senate. Committee on Energy and Natural Resources. Outer continental shelf revenues: Hearing before the Committee on Energy and Natural Resources, United States Senate, Ninety-ninth Congress, first session, on the distribution of outer continental shelf section 8(g) revenues in response to instructions from the budget resolution, September 24, 1985. Washington: U.S. G.P.O., 1986.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

United States. Congress. Senate. Committee on Energy and Natural Resources. Outer continental shelf revenues: Hearing before the Committee on Energy and Natural Resources, United States Senate, Ninety-ninth Congress, first session, on the distribution of outer continental shelf section 8(g) revenues in response to instructions from the budget resolution, September 24, 1985. Washington: U.S. G.P.O., 1986.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Office, General Accounting. Mineral revenues: Cost and revenue information needed to compare different approaches for collecting federal oil and gas royalties : report to congressional requesters. [Washington, D.C.]: The Office, 2004.

Find full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
More sources

Book chapters on the topic "Revenues sharing"

1

Arellano-Yanguas, Javier, and Andrés Mejía-Acosta. "Sharing the Wealth: The Politics of Subnational Distribution of Natural Resource Revenues." In Social Policy in a Development Context, 237–66. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2020. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-37595-9_8.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Gassmann, Oliver, Karolin Frankenberger, and Michaela Choudury. "Revenue Sharing." In Geschäftsmodelle entwickeln, 302–6. München: Carl Hanser Verlag GmbH & Co. KG, 2020. http://dx.doi.org/10.3139/9783446467620.044.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Gassmann, Oliver, Karolin Frankenberger, and Michaela Csik. "Revenue Sharing." In Geschäftsmodelle entwickeln, 281–85. München: Carl Hanser Verlag GmbH & Co. KG, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.3139/9783446452848.044.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Gassmann, Oliver, Karolin Frankenberger, and Michaela Csik. "Revenue Sharing." In Geschäftsmodelle entwickeln, 208–10. München: Carl Hanser Verlag GmbH & Co. KG, 2013. http://dx.doi.org/10.3139/9783446437654.044.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Mungamuru, Bobji, and Hector Garcia-Molina. "Predictive Pricing and Revenue Sharing." In Lecture Notes in Computer Science, 53–60. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 2008. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-92185-1_14.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Shome, Parthasarathi. "Tax Assignment and Revenue Sharing." In Taxation History, Theory, Law and Administration, 117–27. Cham: Springer International Publishing, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-68214-9_12.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Chen, Yiling, Arpita Ghosh, Randolph Preston McAfee, and David Pennock. "Sharing Online Advertising Revenue with Consumers." In Lecture Notes in Computer Science, 556–65. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 2008. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-92185-1_62.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Banfield, Edward C. "Revenue Sharing in Theory and Practice." In Here the People Rule, 110–22. Boston, MA: Springer US, 1985. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4613-2481-2_6.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Çetiner, Demet. "Selfish Revenue Sharing Mechanisms for Airline Alliances." In Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems, 111–32. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 2013. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-35822-7_7.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Unno, Masaru, and Hua Xu. "Dynamic Optimal Revenue-Sharing Strategy in E-Commerce." In Knowledge-Based and Intelligent Information and Engineering Systems, 310–19. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg, 2011. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-23854-3_33.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Conference papers on the topic "Revenues sharing"

1

LoRe, Anthony, Paul Stoller, and Robert Hauser. "Maximizing Energy Revenues: Providing the Best Incentive to the Contract Operator." In 14th Annual North American Waste-to-Energy Conference. ASMEDC, 2006. http://dx.doi.org/10.1115/nawtec14-3184.

Full text
Abstract:
Communities that own waste-to-energy (WTE) facilities rely heavily on the revenues generated by their facility to help pay for the costs to finance, operate and maintain these facilities. The two primary revenue streams are tipping fees and energy sales, generally in the form of electricity. While communities often retain all of the tipping fee revenue, revenue from the sale of energy is nearly always shared with the contract operator. In some cases the shared energy revenues include both capacity and electricity payments. The basis of this strategy is to offer the contract operator an added incentive to maximize this revenue stream through more efficient operation and, in the case of capacity payments, to meet certain capacity commitment criteria required by the energy purchaser. This strategy recognizes that the contract operator has some degree of control over the factors that affect energy production. Under most existing service agreements, which date back to the 1980s, energy revenues are shared on a 90/10 basis, with 90 percent going to the community. Now that many of these service agreements are coming up for renewal or are expiring, communities will need to revisit how best to share energy revenues with the contract operator in order to maximize the total revenues retained by the community. This paper analyzes several different approaches to sharing energy revenues in light of the operational experience gained over the past 20 plus years and concludes that, while energy revenue sharing is still in the best interest of the community, the widely employed strategy of a 90/10 split may not offer the best incentive, and therefore may not lead to the maximization of energy revenues to the community.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Kalogiros, Costas, Hanne Kristine Hallingby, and Olai Bendik Erdal. "5G ecosystem dilemmas: sharing roles and revenues." In 2020 European Conference on Networks and Communications (EuCNC). IEEE, 2020. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/eucnc48522.2020.9200932.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

Mohamed, Ibrahim, and Muhammad Iqbal Mohd Yunus. "Rationalising PSC Fiscal System Principles for Sustainable Future." In International Petroleum Technology Conference. IPTC, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.2523/iptc-21853-ms.

Full text
Abstract:
Abstract PSC fiscal system serves as a framework to determine the sharing of petroleum revenues between stakeholders. Understanding its behavior is essential, given the nature and duration of upstream projects. The paper rationalizes fiscal systems that can promote a balanced, progressive, and robust revenue-sharing mechanism. The impact and efficiency of three typical fiscal regimes are assessed by observing how they react to different scenarios and outcomes, which could be either better or worse than the initial expectation. The three typical fiscal regimes are fixed-rate, production sliding scale sharing, and profitability-based sharing. The early days’ fixed rate sharing system is rigid and does not effectively address the different scales of upstream project investments and the associated uncertainties. The production sliding scale sharing is a partially progressive system that addresses production level variation but does not respond to the variation of other value drivers such as actual cost, price volatility, and project schedule. The profitability based fiscal term represents a progressive win-win system that is more robust, self-regulating, and balances stakeholders’ value objectives. Profitability-based sharing also promotes subsequent field developments. New investment lowers the profitability ratio, which in turn increases contractor profit share percentage. This mechanism results in higher incremental value to the contractor when developing the next field. Compared to the fixed-rate and production sliding scale based sharing, the profitability based sharing could provide a fiscal balance system that is self-regulating, progressive, and more robust. It fits nicely with the oil and gas industry known for the inherent risks and wide range of uncertainties throughout the life of the project. The profitability-based system could be further enhanced to encapsulate the multiple claw-back provisions by switching from the traditional stair-step sharing to a steeper linear sharing with the appropriate ceiling, floor, and triggering points. The linear representation of profitability-based sharing could also complement the various available PSC management control provisions to mitigate the potential cases of opportunistic gold-plating. The sensitive feature of linear sharing could help deter such manipulation. (334)
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Kaplanhan, Fatih, and Cem Korkut. "Distribution of Tax Revenue of Central Government to Local Governments: Glocalization." In International Conference on Eurasian Economies. Eurasian Economists Association, 2014. http://dx.doi.org/10.36880/c05.01127.

Full text
Abstract:
Main questions of this study are “How much autonomy?” and “Has autonomy take to feudalism?” Although the resolution of issue according to effective, efficient, rational and fair principles about the income distribution between the central administration and the municipalities is a precondition of permanent and efficient services of local governments.This study aims to identify regional goverments tasks and improve services of central governments with taxes (VAT) distirbution method. We also aim to increase taxes that are collected from regional governments with the method of glocalization. In addition, if sharing criteria was different, it would how a change between the years 2003-2011 will be investigated. During the comprehensive analysis of these years with public revenues on the basis of VAT, local government’s expenditure, criteria/data to be applied in the share of public revenues to municipalities whether changing the method financing of municipalities can make local governments more efficient and productive will be explored. In a political structure that municipalities are financed from the center, it is very difficult to find an appropriate combination between equality and justice in the distribution of income. Local governments must have privileges which is proportionate with responsibilities on own mandates and source of income for producing to serve as an effective and efficient local services. The results show that if the central governments give budget to regional government according to taxes that are collected in this region, productivity of taxation increase and regional government can collect taxes easier.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

Yuan, Enpeng, and Pascal Van Hentenryck. "Real-Time Pricing Optimization for Ride-Hailing Quality of Service." In Thirtieth International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence {IJCAI-21}. California: International Joint Conferences on Artificial Intelligence Organization, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.24963/ijcai.2021/515.

Full text
Abstract:
When demand increases beyond the system capacity, riders in ride-hailing/ride-sharing systems often experience long waiting time, resulting in poor customer satisfaction. This paper proposes a spatio-temporal pricing framework (AP-RTRS) to alleviate this challenge and shows how it naturally complements state-of-the-art dispatching and routing algorithms. Specifically, the pricing optimization model regulates demand to ensure that every rider opting to use the system is served within reason-able time: it does so either by reducing demand to meet the capacity constraints or by prompting potential riders to postpone service to a later time. The pricing model is a model-predictive control algorithm that works at a coarser temporal and spatial granularity compared to the real-time dispatching and routing, and naturally integrates vehicle relocations. Simulation experiments indicate that the pricing optimization model achieves short waiting times without sacrificing revenues and geographical fairness.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Chiarello, Filippo, Andrea Bonaccorsi, Gualtiero Fantoni, Giacomo Ossola, Andrea Cimino, and Felice Dell'Orletta. "Technical Sentiment Analysis: Measuring Advantages and Drawbacks of New Products Using Social Media." In CARMA 2018 - 2nd International Conference on Advanced Research Methods and Analytics. Valencia: Universitat Politècnica València, 2018. http://dx.doi.org/10.4995/carma2018.2018.8336.

Full text
Abstract:
In recent years, social media have become ubiquitous and important for social networking and content sharing. Moreover, the content generated by these websites remains largely untapped. Some researchers proved that social media have been a valuable source to predict the future outcomes of some events such as box-office movie revenues or political elections. Social media are also used by companies to measure the sentiment of customers about their brand and products. This work proposes a new social media based model to measure how users perceive new products from a technical point of view. This model relies on the analysis of advantages and drawbacks of products, which are both important aspects evaluated by consumers during the buying decision process. This model is based on a lexicon developed in a related work (Chiarello et. al, 2017) to analyse patents and detect advantages and drawbacks connected to a certain technology. The results show that when a product has a certain technological complexity and fuels a more technical debate, advantages and drawbacks analysis is more efficient than sentiment analysis in producing technical-functional judgements.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Susta, Miro R., and Peter Luby. "Compatibility of Advanced Power Generation Technologies With the Independent Power Production." In ASME 1998 International Gas Turbine and Aeroengine Congress and Exhibition. American Society of Mechanical Engineers, 1998. http://dx.doi.org/10.1115/98-gt-222.

Full text
Abstract:
Traditional philosophy of power producing state-owned utilities has been effected by their anonymous risk-sharing attitude. They needn’t have bothered too much with brand-new technologies. Technological risk with unproved, although excellent nominal performance machinery was born by the end-users. On the other hand, independent power producers’ (IPP) philosophy is a little bit different. Their attitude is much more effected by risk evaluation. They have pretty good reasons to be risk-averse with technologies lacking a proven operational record. Any failure to obey their contractual liabilities could mean dramatic consequences to them. Consequently, old-fashioned players in the power generation industry may seem to have been pushing industry technical progress more effectively ahead than it would be with modem players - IPPs. But this is only one side of the coin. Quite opposite reasons for IPPs’ affinity to modern technologies are higher performance parameters which offer better revenues to them, more flexible choice of fuel and prompt readiness to react sensitively to market imbalance and volatilities. Obviously, a hardly-defined, yet sensible equilibrium under which both these trends coexist and inter-act here exists. In this paper we shall analyse factors affecting such equilibrium by presenting real examples of gas turbine-dependent power generation technologies.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Chun-Lin Xin, Wei-Min Ma, and Bin Liu. "Competitive revenue sharing contract." In 2008 International Conference on Machine Learning and Cybernetics (ICMLC). IEEE, 2008. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/icmlc.2008.4620677.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Sui, Ru-bin, Guo-fu An, and Song-tao Zhang. "Research on the supply chain revenue-sharing contract under different revenue-sharing ratios." In 2010 International Conference on Logistics Systems and Intelligent Management (ICLSIM). IEEE, 2010. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/iclsim.2010.5461463.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Birmiwal, Sharad, Ravi R. Mazumdar, and Shreyas Sundaram. "Predictable revenue under processor sharing." In 2012 46th Annual Conference on Information Sciences and Systems (CISS). IEEE, 2012. http://dx.doi.org/10.1109/ciss.2012.6310776.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles

Reports on the topic "Revenues sharing"

1

Hubert, Don. Potential Petroleum Revenues for the Government of Kenya: Implications of the proposed 2015 Model Production Sharing Contract. Oxfam, May 2016. http://dx.doi.org/10.21201/2016.608459.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Daley, John. The politics of general revenue sharing: the new federalism in urban perspective. Portland State University Library, January 2000. http://dx.doi.org/10.15760/etd.589.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

S., Assembe-Mvondo, Wong G., Loft L., and Tjajadi J.S. Comparative assessment of forest revenue redistribution mechanisms in Cameroon: Lessons for REDD+ benefit sharing. Center for International Forestry Research (CIFOR), 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.17528/cifor/005738.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Osidoma, Japhet, and Ashiru Mohammed Kinkwa. Creatively Improving Agricultural Practices and Productivity: Pro Resilience Action (PROACT) project, Nigeria. Oxfam, February 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.21201/2021.7260.

Full text
Abstract:
Since April 2016, The European Union and the Oxfam Pro-Resilience Action Project in Kebbi and Adamawa States, Nigeria, have supported poor smallholder rural farmers to improve their agricultural productivity. The project has a specific focus on increasing crop yields per hectare for better land usage, as well as ensuring farmers possess the skills they need to maintain good agricultural practices, such as inputs utilization and climate mitigation strategies, as well as an information-sharing system on weather and market prices. The project uses a Farmer Field School model that continues to serve as a viable platform for rural farmers to access hands-on skills and basic modern farming knowledge and techniques. The case studies presented here demonstrate a significant increase in farmers’ productivity, income and resilience. This approach should be emulated by governments and private sector players to achieve impact at scale in Nigeria’s agricultural sector, which is the country’s top non-oil revenue stream.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!

To the bibliography