To see the other types of publications on this topic, follow the link: Richard Cantillon.

Journal articles on the topic 'Richard Cantillon'

Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles

Select a source type:

Consult the top 42 journal articles for your research on the topic 'Richard Cantillon.'

Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.

You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.

Browse journal articles on a wide variety of disciplines and organise your bibliography correctly.

1

Sirůček, Pavel. "Half-Forgotten Personalities of Economic Thought - Richard Cantillon." Acta Oeconomica Pragensia 23, no. 1 (February 1, 2015): 61–68. http://dx.doi.org/10.18267/j.aop.465.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
2

Thornton, Mark. "Was Richard Cantillon a Mercantilist?" Journal of the History of Economic Thought 29, no. 4 (December 2007): 417–35. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10427710701666495.

Full text
Abstract:
Richard Cantillon is considered by many to be the first economic theorist. His contributions span such diverse topics as methodology, value and price theory, population, money, international trade, business cycles, the circular-flow model of the economy, and the price-specie-flow mechanism. His only known book, Essai sur la Nature du Commerce en Général (hereafter, the Essai), may represent one of the single largest steps forward in the social sciences. Many attempts have been made to classify Richard Cantillon into a well-defined school of thought and he has been claimed as a forerunner by many schools of economic thought, but for purposes of categorization, he is most often placed with the mercantilists. Cantillon lived and wrote before the Physiocrats. He was involved in John Law's Mississippi Bubble, one of the grandest attempts to actualize the mercantilist dream of increasing the supply of money, and he was involved in the merchant trade and merchant banking business, so it would be natural to consider him a mercantilist writer. Those who have classified him as a mercantilist, however, base their categorization mainly on excerpts from the Essai where Cantillon seems to display sympathy with mercantilist policy objectives in such areas as international trade, monetary policy, and economic development.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
3

KOBAYASHI, Noboru. "Richard Cantillon and James Steuart." Nippon Gakushiin kiyo 55, no. 3 (2001): 175–212. http://dx.doi.org/10.2183/tja1948.55.175.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
4

Fox-Genovese, Elizabeth, and Antoin E. Murphy. "Richard Cantillon: Entrepreneur and Economist." American Historical Review 94, no. 3 (June 1989): 711. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1873768.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
5

O'Brien, D. P., and Antoin E. Murphy. "Richard Cantillon: Entrepreneur and Economist." Economic Journal 97, no. 388 (December 1987): 1035. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2233110.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
6

Bordo, Michael D., and Antoin E. Murphy. "Richard Cantillon: Entrepreneur and Economist." Economic History Review 42, no. 3 (August 1989): 424. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2596463.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
7

Groenewegen, P. "Richard Cantillon: entrepreneur and economist." History of Political Economy 21, no. 3 (September 1, 1989): 564–67. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-21-3-564.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
8

Hardie, Alex. "Book Revew: Richard Cantillon: Entrepreuner and Economist." Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 2, no. 2 (July 1987): 153–55. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/02601079x8700200212.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
9

Groenewegen, Peter, and Anthony Brewer. "Richard Cantillon: Pioneer of Economic Theory." Economic Journal 103, no. 418 (May 1993): 762. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2234561.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
10

Tapinos, Georges Photios, and Anthony Brewer. "Richard Cantillon: Pioneer of Economic Theory." Economica 61, no. 242 (May 1994): 260. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2554967.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
11

Kelly, Patrick. "Review: Richard Cantillon: Entrepreneur and Economist." Irish Economic and Social History 15, no. 1 (April 1988): 138–40. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/033248938801500123.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
12

Astigarraga, Jesús, and Juan Zabalza. "Francisco Craywinkel, plagiario de Richard Cantillon (1760-1763)." Mélanges de la Casa de Velázquez, no. 44-2 (November 15, 2014): 225–47. http://dx.doi.org/10.4000/mcv.5831.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
13

Thornton, M. "Richard Cantillon and the Discovery of Opportunity Cost." History of Political Economy 39, no. 1 (March 1, 2007): 97–119. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-2006-025.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
14

Riley, James C. "Richard Cantillon: Entrepreneur and Economist. Antoin E. Murphy." Journal of Modern History 62, no. 1 (March 1990): 149–51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/243406.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
15

Dostaler, Gilles. "Richard Cantillon, théoricien monétaire majeur du XVIIe siècle." Alternatives Économiques 286, no. 12 (December 1, 2009): 76. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/ae.286.0076.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
16

Carvalho, André Roncaglia de, and João Machado Borges Neto. "A economia monetária de Cantillon e o debate moderno entre ortodoxia e heterodoxia." Economia e Sociedade 28, no. 1 (April 2019): 31–51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1982-3533.2019v28n1art03.

Full text
Abstract:
Resumo O artigo retoma a contribuição de Richard Cantillon à ciência econômica no século XVIII. Apesar de distante no tempo, o arcabouço analítico do autor proporciona reflexões importantes acerca dos fenômenos monetários contemporâneos. Um dos elementos mais significativos é a consideração do ponto de injeção da moeda na economia, permitindo uma compreensão minimamente adequada da relação entre os chamados lados monetário e real da economia. Cantillon já fazia, portanto, uma crítica ao postulado quantitativista, o qual estabelecia uma relação de proporcionalidade entre moeda e preços. Como consequência de sua análise, fica claro que o aumento da quantidade de moeda gera efeitos reais duradouros na economia.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
17

Cardao-Pito, Tiago. "Enlightenment value theories and the three levels in fair value accounting." Accounting History 25, no. 4 (July 9, 2020): 625–35. http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1032373220934895.

Full text
Abstract:
I cannot endorse Donleavy’s conclusion that “ fair value” accounting is derived from the eighteen-century economic thinkers: Anne Robert Turgot; Richard Cantillon; and Adam Smith. In his well-written study, Donleavy seems to misperceive fair value accounting as the reporting of accounting items by their market values. However, fair value accounting also advocates a theoretical explanation of how market prices would be formed and why they would be fair values. It is important to clarify this point, because it leads to two subsequent conclusions. First, that the price/value theory in fair value accounting is quite distinct from Turgot, Cantillon and Smith’s theories on the same matter. For instance, Cantillon and Smith suggested cost-based theories of value, where labor was the key element. Second, it is possible to distinguish fair value accounting from periods where the case for reporting accounting rubrics by market values was promoted based on other theoretical motivations.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
18

Murphy, Antoin E. "John Law and Richard Cantillon on the circular flow of income." European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 1, no. 1 (September 1993): 47–62. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10427719300000062.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
19

Berdell, John. "Retrospectives: An Early Supply-Side–Demand-Side Controversy: Petty, Law, Cantillon." Journal of Economic Perspectives 24, no. 4 (November 1, 2010): 207–17. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.24.4.207.

Full text
Abstract:
Early modern Europe in the late seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries witnessed an unprecedented increase in the rate of economic growth, and governments entertained a wide range of proposals aimed at developing and harnessing foreign trade and emerging financial markets. In his magisterial survey of foreign trade doctrine titled Studies in the Theory of International Trade (1936), Jacob Viner pointed out that enlightened authors of that time were often nonbullionist mercantilists: they favored export promotion and import reduction not on the grounds that it would lead to an accumulation of gold, but on the grounds that it would increase trade and employment. My focus here is on how some key economists of this time period—William Petty, John Law, and Richard Cantillon—adumbrated disputes between supply-side and demand-side macroeconomics that have continued to the present day.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
20

Tribe, Keith. "Essay on the Nature of Trade in General. A Variorum Edition, by Richard Cantillon, edited by Richard van den Berg / Essay on the Nature of Trade in General, by Richard Cantillon, edited by Antoin E. Murphy." European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 24, no. 5 (September 3, 2017): 1107–9. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09672567.2017.1366127.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
21

Berdell, John. "Richard van den Berg, ed., Richard Cantillon’s Essay on the Nature of Trade in General: A Variorum Edition, by Richard Cantillon (London and New York: Routledge, 2015), pp. 514, $200. ISBN 978-1-13801-458-9." Journal of the History of Economic Thought 38, no. 4 (November 18, 2016): 543–45. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s1053837216000845.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
22

Menudo, José Manuel, and José María O'Kean. "La recepción de la obra de Jean-Baptiste Say en España: la teoría económica del empresario." Revista de Historia Económica / Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 23, no. 1 (March 2005): 117–42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s0212610900011836.

Full text
Abstract:
RESUMENEste trabajo analiza la difusión de la teoria del empresario de Jean-Baptiste Say en España, como último eslabón de una línea de pensamiento que tiene su origen en Richard Cantillon. Se prueba que la particularidad de este autor es su gran difusión en el siglo XIX español –siendo uno de los más traducidos– y la escasa influencia de su teoría económica del empresario. Explicamos las razones de una paradoja que deja sin fundamentos teóricos a cualquier política económica destinada al desarrollo del tejido empresarial nacional. Son presentados los mecanismos de difusión, tanto directos, por medio de traducciones, como indirectos, por medio de autores españoles que pudieron difundir esta teoría de la función empresarial. Nos interesa conocer la recepción por parte de los autores españoles de la teoría del empresario de Say, determinar su grado de comprensión, de interpretación en relación con la realidad nacional, de revisión teórica, e incluso conocer si la fuente real de la idea a transmitir es el propio autor o alguna otra.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
23

Nathania, Jessica, Christina Whidya Utami, and Timotius Febry. "PERBEDAAN KINERJA ENTREPRENEUR ANTARA PENGUSAHA LAKILAKI DAN PENGUSAHA PEREMPUAN." PERFORMA 5, no. 2 (September 24, 2020): 103–11. http://dx.doi.org/10.37715/jp.v5i1.1537.

Full text
Abstract:
Entrepreneurship merupakan konsep di mana seseorang menciptakan dan mengatur sebuahbisnis untuk mendapatkan keuntungan dengan mengambil risiko di dunia korporasi. Istilahentrepreneurship pertama kali dikenalkan oleh Richard Cantillon pada 1775, diambil dari bahasaPerancis "entreprende" yang berarti "perantara". Berbicara mengenai entrepreneurship, tentu tidaklepas dari profesi entrepreneur atau pengusaha. Selama ini stereotype bekerja, dalam konteks iniberwirausaha, selalu hanya dikaitkan dengan laki-laki. Sementara perempuan lekat dengan citra iburumah tangga yang hanya mengurusi urusan rumah dan anak. Padahal, perempuan juga memiliki minatdalam berwirausaha. Tujuan penelitian ini adalah untuk menganalisis kinerja entrepreneurship antarapengusaha laki-laki dan perempuan dengan variabel bebas gender dan variabel terikat kinerjaentrepreneurship. Penelitian ini menggunakan pendekatan kuantitatif. Populasi penelitian adalahseluruh entrepreneur UMKM di Surabaya Barat dengan syarat berskala mikro dan kecil, serta telahmenjalankan bisnis minimal selama satu tahun. Sampel yang diambil sebanyak 100 orang, terdiri dari 50orang laki-laki dan 50 orang perempuan yang dipilih menggunakan teknik purposive random sampling.Alat pengumpulan data menggunakan kuesioner dan analisis data menggunakan metode tabulasi silangdengan bantuan SPSS 23. Hasil penelitian menyatakan bahwa tidak ada perbedaan kinerjaentrepreneurship antara pengusaha laki-laki dan perempuan.Kata kunci : Kinerja, Pengusaha, Entrepreneurship, Gender
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
24

Klamer, Arjo. "Richard Cantillon: Enterpreneur and Economist. By Antoin E. Murphy. New York: Oxford University Press, 1987. pp. xv, 336. $48.00." Journal of Economic History 48, no. 3 (September 1988): 744–45. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s0022050700006069.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
25

Sabbagh, Gabriel. "CANTILLON IN FRENCH AND ENGLISH. TWO EDITIONS BY RICHARD VAN DEN BERG AND ANTOIN E. MURPHY: NEW FACTS AND HYPOTHESES." Contributions to Political Economy 35, no. 1 (June 2016): 91–126. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/cpe/bzw003.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
26

Astigarraga Goenaga, Jesús, and Juan Zabalza Arbizu. "La fortuna del Essai sur la nature du commerce en général (1755), de Richard Cantillon, en la España del siglo XVIII." Investigaciones de Historia Económica 3, no. 7 (January 2007): 9–36. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/s1698-6989(07)70182-0.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
27

Rössner, Philipp Robinson. "Introduction." History of Political Economy 53, no. 3 (June 1, 2021): 371–87. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-8993260.

Full text
Abstract:
Capitalism is often assumed to have been invented in the Anglosphere. Writings by Hume and Smith have been named as cornerstones in the making of capitalism and modern economic knowledge. But Smith’s and the other Enlightenment Scots’ works built on a commercial tradition that had been manifest in Anglo-Saxon economics since the sixteenth century or earlier. Moreover, this tradition of thinking about commercial society became quite widespread and in the seventeenth and eighteenth century extended to the entire European continent where it has become commonly known, in its manifold regional and national variants, under the general term Cameralism The usual genealogy of capitalist political economy, foundations of which were established by Marx (Capital, Vol. I), starts with William Petty, Richard Cantillon, Turgot and then winds down a well-known line from Adam Smith to David Ricardo, including John Stuart Mill, and Marx himself. The contributions made by continental Cameralists to the shaping of the political economy of modern capitalism on the other hand have tended to be overlooked. The present paper discusses the wider epistemic vantage points of the present special issue, some basic assumptions, as well as the broad contributions made by subsequent papers to the study of Cameralism not only as a near pan-European economic discourse during the early modern period, but also how different authors from a Cameralist vantage point and spectrum contributed to rise of modern economic analysis and modern political economies of capitalism.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
28

Sonenscher, Michael. "Richard Cantillon: Entrepreneur and Economist. By Antoin E. Murphy. New York: Oxford University Press, 1987. xx + 336 pp. Illustrations, charts, tables, appendixes, notes, and index. $48.00." Business History Review 62, no. 4 (1988): 742–43. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3115650.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
29

Menšík, Josef. "The Origins of the Income Theory of Money." Review of Economic Perspectives 14, no. 4 (January 29, 2015): 373–92. http://dx.doi.org/10.1515/revecp-2015-0005.

Full text
Abstract:
Abstract The income theory of money was conceived in the 19th century, and in the first half of the 20th century it formed the backbone of all the main monetary approaches of the time. Yet, since it did so mostly implicitly rather than explicitly, and since the later developments moved economic theory in a different direction, the income theory of money is hardly remembered at present. While mainly accounting for the origins of the approach, I am also offering a brief comparison with the present mainstream economics and I shortly address the question of the possible future of the theory too. The income theory of money explains how nominal prices are formed by interaction of nominal expenditures streams with real streams of goods sold. While various ideas leading to this theory were expressed already by John Law, Richard Cantillon, and Jean-Baptiste Say, it is perhaps only Thomas Tooke whom we might want to call the originator of the theory. Within the Classical School of Political Economy, Tooke's ideas were further elaborated by John Stuart Mill. The theory reached a momentous formulation in the works of Knut Wicksell, in many respects a similar exposition was delivered also by Friedrich Wieser. The recognition of the theory was impaired by a change of the main-stream paradigm as well as by a surge in emphasis laid on the quantitative modelling in economics. Yet, there are certain fundamental questions of the monetary theory which the general equilibrium style models cannot cope with, while the income theory of money can, at least to a certain degree. This might give the theory some hope for the future.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
30

Berdell, John, and José M. Menudo. "Richard Cantillon’s stabilizing market dynamics." European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 27, no. 4 (May 29, 2020): 476–99. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09672567.2020.1770988.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
31

Imoisi, Imoisi. "Richard Cantillon’s Ideologies and Its Implications for Economic Development in Nigeria." IOSR Journal of Humanities and Social Science 10, no. 1 (2013): 27–32. http://dx.doi.org/10.9790/0837-01012732.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
32

Brewer, Anthony. "Richard Cantillon's Essay on the Nature of Trade in General: A Variorum Edition." History of Political Economy 49, no. 3 (September 2017): 531–34. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-4201530.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
33

Murphy, Antoin E. "Richard Cantillon’s essay on the nature of trade in general. A variorum edition." History of Economics Review 66, no. 1 (January 2, 2017): 72–73. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10370196.2017.1304797.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
34

Brewer, A. "An Essay on Economic Theory: An English Translation of Richard Cantillon's Essai sur la nature du commerce en general." History of Political Economy 44, no. 4 (December 1, 2012): 693–95. http://dx.doi.org/10.1215/00182702-1811397.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
35

Théré, Christine. "van den Berg Richard (ed.), 2015, Richard Cantillon’s Essay on the Nature of Trade in General. A variorum edition, London, Routledge, Routledge studies in the history of economics, XV-513 p." Population 72, no. 1 (2017): 166. http://dx.doi.org/10.3917/popu.1701.0166.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
36

Mousten Hansen, Kristoffer. "The first modern economist." MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 7, no. 3 (November 7, 2019). http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2019.v7.1244.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
37

Thornton, Mark. "Richard Cantillon and the Origin of Economic Theory." Journal des Économistes et des Études Humaines 8, no. 1 (January 1, 1998). http://dx.doi.org/10.1515/jeeh-1998-0104.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
38

Thornton, Mark. "Why Did Cantillon Change the Meaning of Entrepreneurship?" MISES: Interdisciplinary Journal of Philosophy, Law and Economics 7, no. 3 (November 7, 2019). http://dx.doi.org/10.30800/mises.2019.v7.1241.

Full text
Abstract:
In breaking with the policy regime of mercantilism, Richard Cantillon put forth a manuscript in 1730, wherein he produced the first treatise of economic theory. Key to this development was his new theory of entrepreneurship which allowed him to construct economic theories and concepts. Recent research has shown that he did not coin the term, but rather radically changed the meaning of an existing term, to its near opposite. This paper explores why he changed the meaning of the entrepreneur. The speculative answer is both theoretical and based on his life experience.
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
39

"Antoin E. Murphy. Richard Cantillon: Entrepreneur and Economist. New York: Clarendon Press of Oxford University Press. 1986. Pp. vii, 336. $48.00." American Historical Review, June 1989. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/ahr/94.3.711.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
40

Brady, Michael Emmett. "A Straightforward Demonstration of Adam Smith's Vast Intellectual Superiority Over Richard Cantillon on Issues Related to the Relative Roles of Uncertainty and Risk in Economic and Decision Theory." SSRN Electronic Journal, 2015. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2637289.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
41

Challoumis, Constantinos. "The Commerce in the Middle Ages from the View of Richard Cantillon’s Approach." SSRN Electronic Journal, 2018. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3261911.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
42

Giacomin, Alberto. ""Power and Trade in the Economy of the "Ancien Régime": A Re-Interpretation of Richard Cantillon's "Essay"." Jahrbuch für Wirtschaftsgeschichte / Economic History Yearbook 35, no. 2 (January 1994). http://dx.doi.org/10.1524/jbwg.1994.35.2.131.

Full text
APA, Harvard, Vancouver, ISO, and other styles
We offer discounts on all premium plans for authors whose works are included in thematic literature selections. Contact us to get a unique promo code!

To the bibliography