Academic literature on the topic 'Vices du consentement'
Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles
Consult the lists of relevant articles, books, theses, conference reports, and other scholarly sources on the topic 'Vices du consentement.'
Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.
You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.
Journal articles on the topic "Vices du consentement"
Le Moulec, Éliaz. "Réforme du droit des obligations : quelques éléments relatifs aux vices du consentement." Revue juridique de l'Ouest 29, no. 3 (2016): 39–50. http://dx.doi.org/10.3406/juro.2016.4877.
Full textNeirinck, Claire, and Maryline Bruggeman. "Les aménagements consensuels que les couples appliquent à leur rupture sont-ils d’essence contractuelle ?" Les Cahiers de droit 49, no. 4 (June 3, 2009): 551–69. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/037457ar.
Full textCharpentier, Élise. "Les fondements théoriques de la transformation du rôle de l’équilibre des prestations contractuelles." Les Cahiers de droit 45, no. 1 (April 12, 2005): 69–91. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/043784ar.
Full textFarget, Doris, and Marie-Pier Fullum-Lavery. "La place réservée à l’avis des peuples autochtones dans le cadre du processus de prise de décision concernant le Plan Nord ou l’exploitation du Nord québécois : perspective juridique interne et internationale." McGill Law Journal 59, no. 3 (May 21, 2014): 595–653. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/1025140ar.
Full textMacDonald, Noni E., Shawn Harmon, and Janice E. Graham. "Examen déontologique des programmes d’immunisation de la santé publique au Canada." Relevé des maladies transmissibles au Canada 47, no. 04 (May 7, 2021): 259–64. http://dx.doi.org/10.14745/ccdr.v47i04a09f.
Full textMorin, Michel. "La nature du contrat de transaction et le problème de la novation." Revue générale de droit 20, no. 2 (March 28, 2019): 195–234. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/1058484ar.
Full textCosnard, Henri-Daniel. "Cour d'appel de Rennes (6e ch, 2e sect.) 12 mai 1989 : Divorce sur demande acceptée - Vice du consentement - Appel du jugement - Recevabilité (oui) - Appréciation - Maladie - Rejet." Revue juridique de l'Ouest 2, no. 3 (1989): 437–42. http://dx.doi.org/10.3406/juro.1989.1744.
Full textLavallée, Carmen. "Le secret de l’adoption en France et au Québec." Revue générale de droit 27, no. 4 (March 23, 2016): 441–73. http://dx.doi.org/10.7202/1035751ar.
Full textDissertations / Theses on the topic "Vices du consentement"
Pfalzgraf, Nathalie. "Vulnérabilité et vices du consentement." Thesis, Strasbourg, 2015. http://www.theses.fr/2015STRAA028.
Full textA recent phenomenon is the introduction in the law of less legal concepts with higher elasticity, which give the judge a broader discretion. This is the case for the concept of vulnerability. Although vulnerability was never completely absent from our law, more amazing is the fact that this notion is taken into consideration in the jurisprudence relating to defects of consent even if in contradiction with the texts of the Civil Code. If this term has been used it is because the Jurisprudence has since a long time distorted the meaning of the texts. To better understand this concept, a detour by other institutions will determine its future concerning defects of consent. The different French or European projects of contract law reform are also considering this notion. However, these discussions demonstrate that its introduction in the texts relating to the defect of consent is challenging
Valoteau, Aude. "La théorie des vices du consentement et le droit pénal /." Aix-en-Provence : Presses Univ. d'Aix-Marseille, PUAM, 2006. http://www.gbv.de/dms/spk/sbb/recht/toc/520818334.pdf.
Full textValoteau, Aude Maistre Du Chambon Patrick. "La théorie des vices du consentement et le droit pénal /." [Aix-en-Provence] : Presses universitaires d'Aix-Marseille-PUAM, 2006. http://catalogue.bnf.fr/ark:/12148/cb40196394z.
Full textSiri, Romain. "La théorie générale des vices du consentement, entre mythe et réalité ? /." Aix-en-Provence : Presses universitaires d'Aix-Marseille, 2008. http://catalogue.bnf.fr/ark:/12148/cb41273239q.
Full textMaume, Florian. "Essai critique sur la protection du consentement de la partie faible en matière contractuelle." Thesis, Evry-Val d'Essonne, 2015. http://www.theses.fr/2015EVRY0012/document.
Full textThe notion of « weak contracting party » is not conceptualized in French contract law. However, it is frequently invoked to the point of having been behind the creation of entire sections of law, such as consumer law. Therefore, the situation is paradoxical. Besides that, the protection of those presumed « weak contracting parties » are multiple, scattered and often ineffective. It is consequently appropriate to conceptualize this notion, and thereby clarify the protection of its consent. Moreover, these creations should be incorporated in the Civil Code, in order to constitute a genuine common law benefiting all, rather than a series of exceptions benefiting only some contractors
Vilotitch, Drag Yov. "De la nullité du mariage pour vices du consentement en droit français et dans les principales législations étrangères." Lyon : Université Lyon3, 2006. http://thesesbrain.univ-lyon3.fr/sdx/theses/lyon3/1990/vilotitch_y.
Full textJakouloff, Karim. "L'influence des droits de la consommation et de la concurrence sur la théorie des vices du consentement." Thesis, Paris Est, 2013. http://www.theses.fr/2013PEST0094.
Full textThe theory of the defect of consent offers a generic protection of the contracting party against all risk of consent modification. Having noticed its inadequacy, the laws of consumerism and competition have chosen to adopt a set of specific rules aiming to protect on one hand the consumer, and on the other hand the professional, both in a weak negotiating position, against these same risks. Within the consumerism law, this has been achieved under the European Rights impetus. The 11 May 2005 directive concerning unfair business-to-consumer commercial practices has largely dictated the content of the protective measures nowadays applicable to customers. In the same way, the Second Title of the First Book of Consumer Code, dedicated to commercial practices, consists of a preliminary chapter establishing the unfair business-to-consumer commercial practices. It follows by the 1st chapter, where the 1st section deals with misleading commercial practices, whilst the 2nd chapter, 5th section deals with aggressive commercial practices. Hence the competition law has resorted spontaneously to this option. Fourth Book includes fourth Chapter, where the second Chapter relates to the ban of competitive restrictive practices. These ones, forbidden per se, apparently have no link to this theory of the defect of consent. However, if we look closer, some of them have indirectly the aim to balance present forces at the negotiation stage via a distribution contract between professionals. In fact some will be keen to ban certain professional's behavior that, having a certain economical advantage, could be tempted to play in such a way so as to acquire unjustified contractual advantages from contractual partners, economically dependent. In doing so, the latter would need to have their consent protected.By developing such legislation, special laws have distanced themselves from their mutual purpose. Thus, if it is true that the consumerism law offers a set of rules aiming to prevent any defect of consent should it arise, it equally proposes a multitude of preventive rules but of a delicate maneuver – this being an original approach within the theory of defect of consent of common law, trying to repress the abuse effectively altering the contractual consent. Their comprehension as well as the putting it into practice would require a certain skill, to the point of risking the protection effectiveness that it aims to provide. As to the competition law, a set of rules aiming to forbid per se sensitive behavior, it would endanger only particular interests of professionals in a weak negotiating position, and not the whole market, manifestly tending to divert the matter from its initial result.To find a solution to these observations would imply to take into account the possibility of cutting off special rights of certain legal rules aiming to protect contractual consent they are under the obligation of, in favor of the theory of defect of consent. Such solution would lead to re-focusing on consumer and competition laws around their respective result, which are on one hand the protection of consumer's personal interests, and on the other hand market protection. It would then mean that the contracting party, sheltered by special rules, would not see their protection level diminish. To be re-assured there's the need to determine the nature of the improvements the theory of defect of consent would require, so as to include a part of the litigation of special law. The latter, inspired by a study of special law, could then benefit of the whole contractual under the common law
Waltz, Bélinda. "Le dol dans la formation des contrats : essai d'une nouvelle théorie." Thesis, Lyon 3, 2011. http://www.theses.fr/2011LYO30109.
Full textProfessional, or the increasing use of adhesion contracts (“take it or leave it agreements”), all are factors that can lead to the contractor’s vulnerability. The risk is, for the so-called “strong” party, to abuse its position in order to force the other party into a strongly unbalanced agreement, mainly in its own benefit. Since such a reprehensible behavior occurs during the contract formation, the weakened party should be able to find protection through the use of the defects of consent theory. However, this theory has proven inadequate to effectively protect abused contractors today. A major explanation is due to the fact that this theory remains unchanged since 1804. Based on an individualistic conception of the contract, conditions of admission of each defects of consent, such as error, abuse and fraud, are too restrictive. However, the more contractual inequalities exist, the more they will turn into abuse. Therefore, this is why such a theory should be restored in order to protect contractors. It is through the notion of “dol” (willful misrepresentation or fraudulent concealment) that we propose to do so. This choice is not a coincidence. It is justified by the fact that “dol” is a tort, even before being a defect of consent. Specifically, it is the manifestation of pre-contractual disloyalty. Its recognition as a fact altering willpower will generate two negative effects. The first is linked to the fact that “dol” appears to be a complex notion and a source of contradiction in substantive law. The second is not permitting to properly penalize the dishonesty perpetrated during the contract formation due to a too narrow scope of the “dol”, the latter being understood as an induced error. Giving it back its real nature of a civil tort defecting the contract and undermining the pre-contractual good faith, our work aims at finding a remedy to these two shortcomings
Marie, Alexis. "Le silence de l'Etat comme manifestation de sa volonté." Thesis, Paris 2, 2013. http://www.theses.fr/2013PA020061.
Full text. During the work of the International Law Commission regarding Unilateral Acts of States, the Special Rapporteur denied that State’s silence could be qualified as a manifestation of its will. Nevertheless,no theoretical reason justifies this position. The study of the practice reveals more over that, as the casemay be, State’s silence can be qualified as refusal or as acquiescence and that it plays a fundamental role in the formation, the interpretation or the modification of legal interstate relations. Indeed, since it is the State’s prerogative to appreciate the legality of the behavior of others States, legal certainty imposes to hold the legal relevance of their silence. Under its diverse facets, this objective constitutes the raison d’être of the effect attributed to silence and thus allows a systematization of the various hypothesis in which it is taken into account. Depending on the situation to which it reacts, silence ensures the current or future determination of legal relations. Furthermore, the study of the conditions necessary for the production of the silence’s effects reveals that positive law consecrates the theoretical possibility of qualifying silence as a legal act. International law requires, in order toattribute an effect to silence, that the silent State was free to react and had knowledge of the situation that made his silence legally relevant. Moreover, the rules governing the proof of the knowledge and of the existence of silence do not necessarily justify the criticism towards the fictive character of the voluntarist explanation of the phenomena. There is, in any event, no legal fiction in qualifying silenceas a legal act
Machefaux, Erwan. "L'obligation d'information dans les cessions de contrôle." Thesis, Paris 1, 2020. http://www.theses.fr/2020PA01D042.
Full textTransfers of control are a particular type of share transfer, with their own legal framework, as they form, at the same time, the main means of transferring companies. As such, they are a major economic challenge; difficult to control since the company itself is a complex construct. Moreover, there is an important imbalance of knowledge in relation to the transferred company between the parties. Also, very frequently, transfers of control disputes arise from an event occurring after the transfer, but which originates during the period of management by the transferor. The transferee is therefore disappointed by the devaluation of the shares and has to deal with the adverse consequences following its acquisition of the company. In the first instance, the main recourses available to the disappointed transferee allowing notably the sanction of the violation of the transferor’s duty to inform are examined within the legal framework. This includes notably the defects in consent (mistake and fraud), the guarantees related to the sale (the guarantee against latent defects and the guarantee against dispossession), as well as the duty to inform formalized by the reform of French contract law dated 10 February 2016. In the second instance, the main agreements which formalize the operation and allow the parties to deal contractually with such duty to inform are analyzed. This comprises notably the liability guarantee, price adjustment clauses and due diligence. The recourse to professional experts and the reliability of information provided are also examined. This analysis through the spectrum of the duty to inform sheds an updated light on transfers of control. It contains the tools to assess the chances of success of the different recourses available and the implementation of a global legal strategy
Books on the topic "Vices du consentement"
Valoteau, Aude. La théorie des vices du consentement et le droit pénal. Aix-en-Provence: Presses universitaires d'Aix-Marseille, 2006.
Find full textBook chapters on the topic "Vices du consentement"
"LES VICES DU CONSENTEMENT À MARIAGE (200)." In Le mariage dans l'oeuvre de Flavius Josephe, 95–101. Peeters Publishers, 2021. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/j.ctv1qp9g77.12.
Full text