Academic literature on the topic 'Willing buyer-willing seller'
Create a spot-on reference in APA, MLA, Chicago, Harvard, and other styles
Consult the lists of relevant articles, books, theses, conference reports, and other scholarly sources on the topic 'Willing buyer-willing seller.'
Next to every source in the list of references, there is an 'Add to bibliography' button. Press on it, and we will generate automatically the bibliographic reference to the chosen work in the citation style you need: APA, MLA, Harvard, Chicago, Vancouver, etc.
You can also download the full text of the academic publication as pdf and read online its abstract whenever available in the metadata.
Journal articles on the topic "Willing buyer-willing seller"
Shahanaghi, Kamran, and Maryam Keyvani Rad. "New Approach of Multistage Model in Supply Chain with Game Theory." Modern Applied Science 10, no. 4 (February 2, 2016): 112. http://dx.doi.org/10.5539/mas.v10n4p112.
Full textLahiff, Edward. "‘Willing buyer, willing seller’: South Africa's failed experiment in market-led agrarian reform." Third World Quarterly 28, no. 8 (December 2007): 1577–97. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/01436590701637417.
Full textBECKER, BRIAN, and GARY GUTZLER. "Should a Blockage Discount Apply? Perspectives of Both a Hypothetical Willing Buyer and a Hypothetical Willing Seller." Business Valuation Review 19, no. 1 (March 2000): 3–9. http://dx.doi.org/10.5791/0882-2875-19.1.3.
Full textSoberman, David A. "Simultaneous Signaling and Screening with Warranties." Journal of Marketing Research 40, no. 2 (May 2003): 176–92. http://dx.doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.40.2.176.19228.
Full textSebola, M. P., and J. P. Tsheola. "Economics of Agricultural Land Restitution and Redistribution in South Africa: Willing-Seller, Willing-Buyer Business Imperatives Versus Socio-political Transformation?" Journal of Human Ecology 46, no. 2 (May 2014): 113–23. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09709274.2014.11906712.
Full textKim, Seong-Cheol, and Surender Reddy Salkuti. "Optimal power flow based congestion management using enhanced genetic algorithms." International Journal of Electrical and Computer Engineering (IJECE) 9, no. 2 (April 1, 2019): 875. http://dx.doi.org/10.11591/ijece.v9i2.pp875-883.
Full textDeksnytė, Indrė, Zigmas Lydeka, and Violeta Pukelienė. "DYNAMIC PRICE AS BARGAINING RESULT FOR REVENUE MAXIMIZATION IN RETAIL." Ekonomika 93, no. 3 (January 1, 2014): 67–83. http://dx.doi.org/10.15388/ekon.2014.0.3883.
Full textHorn, Alison Van. "Redefining “Property”: The Constitutional Battle over Land Redistribution in Zimbabwe." Journal of African Law 38, no. 2 (1994): 144–72. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/s0021855300005490.
Full textWang, Jiqiang, Fu Gu, Yingpeng Liu, Ying Fan, and Jianfeng Guo. "An Endowment Effect Study in the European Union Emission Trading Market based on Trading Price and Price Fluctuation." International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 17, no. 9 (May 11, 2020): 3343. http://dx.doi.org/10.3390/ijerph17093343.
Full textDu Plessis, Elmien WJ. "Silence is Golden: The Lack of Direction on Compensation for Expropriation in the 2011 Green Paper on Land Reform." Potchefstroom Electronic Law Journal/Potchefstroomse Elektroniese Regsblad 17, no. 2 (April 21, 2017): 830. http://dx.doi.org/10.17159/1727-3781/2014/v17i2a2186.
Full textDissertations / Theses on the topic "Willing buyer-willing seller"
Dlamini, Siphiwe. "Taking land reform seriously: From willing seller-willing buyer to expropriation." Master's thesis, University of Cape Town, 2014. http://hdl.handle.net/11427/4691.
Full textHenning, Ineke. "Implications of land reform on spatial planning and development in the Tzaneen Local Municipality / I. Henning." Thesis, North-West University, 2010. http://hdl.handle.net/10394/4400.
Full textThesis (M.Art. et Scien. (Town and Regional Planning))--North-West University, Potchefstroom Campus, 2010.
Britain-Renecke, Cézanne. "Potential alternative sources of funding South Africa's land redistribution programme in its agricultural sector." University of the Western Cape, 2011. http://hdl.handle.net/11394/3048.
Full textMadletyana, Philani. "Race, gender, class and land reform: a case study approach on the land reform for agricultural development (LRAD) sub-programme." Thesis, 2012. http://hdl.handle.net/10539/11018.
Full textThe racial discrimination under colonialism and apartheid culminated to the dispossession of black people from their land, and to unequal land distribution between black and white people. Territorial segregation during this period was not only about the displacement of black people from their land and their deprivation to equal access to land compared to their white counterparts, it was also about economic deprivation, eradication of subsistence agriculture and the transformation of blacks into wage labourers (Hall, 2004; Walker, 2008).The post-apartheid land reform process was initiated to redress the injustices and inequalities of the past. It took a market-driven approach to blend the objectives of land reform with those of national reconciliation and maintenance of food security (DLA, 1997). The land reform process took a form of restoring land to its original owners who were forcefully removed from it after June 1913 or compensation if land could not be restored. It was also aimed at securing tenure rights for farm workers, labour tenants, farm dwellers and people residing in communal areas. The aims of the third part of the land reform programme was to redistribute 30% of commercial farms in white hands to black people with the view of redressing racial disparities in landholding. As early as in the initial stages of the development of South Africa’s land policy in the early 1990s, scholars and civil society groups warned about the ineffectiveness of the market to deliver on land reform objectives. This paper adopts a case study approach to study the South African land reform process in relation to the notion of empowerment. It focuses on the Land Reform for Agricultural Development (LRAD) sub-programme by looking at the intersection between race, gender and class. Bambanani Fruits (Pty) Ltd, an LRAD project based in the Gauteng province is used as a case study. This is an LRAD Equity Scheme project, meaning that its beneficiaries (who are former workers on the farm) acquired an LRAD grant to purchase equity shares to be co-owners of the project. Bambanani Fruits is a successful project considering its productivity and access to the market. This paper investigates how much LRAD beneficiaries are part of this success i.e. whether they have agency, whether they feel a sense of ownership and control of the project, and the extent at which they take part in decision making in the project. This task is carried out through the application of Kabeer’s (1999) instrumentalist model of measuring empowerment. Kabeer states that empowerment is measured by looking at three aspects, namely; resources, agency and achievement. Kabeer’s model is applied to the data which was collected through various means including in depth interviews with Bambanani LRAD beneficiaries and land officials from the province, document analysis and review of existing scholarly work on land reform. It is well documented that South Africa’s land reform process has been very slow in delivering to its objectives, and departmental reports used in this paper also confirm this assertion. The research results reveal that even though more land was transferred under LRAD, the sub-programme also encountered some of the challenges and hindrances faced by its predecessor Settlement/Land Acquisition Grant (SLAG). It faced budgetary constraints, complexities of the land market such as price restrictions and resistance by land owners to cede land, and so on. Generally, it was found that LRAD tended to entrench race, gender and class disparities in landholding. At Bambanani, I discovered that LRAD has affected beneficiaries differently. The sub-programme has stratified these beneficiaries into competing class factions. Divergent interests have emerged to distort the actual meaning of empowerment. I have labelled this tension a ‘dichotomous factionalism’. The struggle and conflict is caught up between beneficiaries themselves, and their disunity has left the hegemony of the farm’s management unchallenged. I argue that, their empowerment is firstly condemned from within and this internal condemnation limits their negotiating power with the management. Secondly, their empowerment is curtailed by the farm’s management in such as way that it sometimes uses its majority shares to justify unilateral decision making. According to Kabeer, empowerment ought to encompass egalitarian decision making. Respondents have reported this is not always being the case at Bambanani. One group of participants complained about how things have remained the same on the farm despite the acquisition of LRAD shares to co-own the farm. Another group which is mostly comprised by trust members argued that things have changed for the better compared to the period prior to the attainment of these equity shares. In doing so, this group blames the discontent group for the lack of commitment to the project and for being after money over the interest of the project. The discontent group has also complained that the trust is not representing their interests to the management, and whenever they lay complaints there are often threats of expulsion. Apart from the above mentioned conflict of interests amongst Bambanani beneficiaries, positive elements were also discovered where beneficiaries agreed on some areas of dissatisfaction. I have labelled this a Collective Discontent Spectacle. The plight of beneficiaries is caused by the lack of adequate exposure to the business side of the farm’s operation and the lack of delivery on houses which were promised to them by the management as part of the shareholding package. Having considered the Bambanani case and other literature on LRAD, I concluded that LRAD has failed to fulfil empowerment requirements as per Kabeer’s model.
Britain-Renecke, Cézanne. "Potential alternative sources of funding South Africaâs land redistribution programme in its agricultural sector." Thesis, 2011. http://etd.uwc.ac.za/index.php?module=etd&action=viewtitle&id=gen8Srv25Nme4_5348_1366188206.
Full textBook chapters on the topic "Willing buyer-willing seller"
Baskind, Eric, Greg Osborne, and Lee Roach. "14. Delivery and payment." In Commercial Law, 320–39. Oxford University Press, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/he/9780198825975.003.0014.
Full textClarke, MA, RJA Hooley, RJC Munday, LS Sealy, AM Tettenborn, and PG Turner. "12. Performance of the contract." In Commercial Law. Oxford University Press, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/he/9780199692088.003.0012.
Full textSmith, Alan D. "Consumers' Concerns for Reputation and Identity Theft Online Trading." In Advances in IT Standards and Standardization Research, 200–238. IGI Global, 2019. http://dx.doi.org/10.4018/978-1-5225-7214-5.ch010.
Full textSmith, Alan D. "Linking the Popularity of Online Trading with Consumers’ Concerns for Reputation and Identity Theft." In Web-Based Multimedia Advancements in Data Communications and Networking Technologies, 1–35. IGI Global, 2013. http://dx.doi.org/10.4018/978-1-4666-2026-1.ch001.
Full text"If these requirements are met, the seller is bound to take such steps as are reasonable to preserve the goods. The measures that ought to be taken will depend on the circumstances of the individual case. Usually, the seller will have to store the goods and protect them against damage. Under certain circumstances, it will be obliged to resell them (Art. 88(2) CISG). Art. 85, sentence 1 CISG adopts a lower standard than that of Art. 79 CISG, in that the seller may refrain from taking steps, even if they are within its control, if such steps would cause unreasonable costs or are otherwise disproportionate. The duty to preserve the goods ends at the time at which the buyer takes delivery or declares the contract avoided, or where the seller undertakes a resale (Art. 88). The seller is entitled to withhold the goods until the buyer reimburses it for the costs of storage and preservation (Art. 85, sentence 2). Questions Q 85-1 a) What is the function of Arts 85 to 88 CISG? b) Which party do they address? c) Which general rule is reflected in Art. 85 CISG? Q 85-2 What are the consequences if the party who is bound to preserve the goods does not comply with its duty? Q 85-3 Who bears the preservation costs under Art. 85 CISG if the buyer’s refusal to take delivery is justified? Q 85-4 Does Art. 85 CISG apply in the following situations where the seller pre-serves the goods after a) having tendered conforming goods of which the buyer does not take delivery, b) having tendered goods that are evidently non-conforming (= funda-mental breach) of which the buyer does not take delivery, c) having tendered too late (but non-delivery does not amount to fundamental breach) and the buyer does not take delivery, d) having tendered properly and the buyer is willing to take delivery of the goods but unjustifiably refuses to pay the purchase price, e) having tendered and the buyer is willing to take delivery of the goods and to pay the purchase price, but declares that it does not feel bound to the sales distribution agreement concluded between the parties. Without sticking to the distribution agreement, the seller will be deprived of what it was entitled to expect under the contract and will no longer be interested in upholding the contract, f) having tendered and the buyer takes delivery of only part of the goods, because there is allegedly no larger storage room available. Q 85-5 In view of Q 85-4, in which situations alone will the seller not be bound to." In International Sales Law, 640. Routledge-Cavendish, 2007. http://dx.doi.org/10.4324/9780203945445-232.
Full textConference papers on the topic "Willing buyer-willing seller"
Kotut, Lindah, Timothy L. Stelter, Michael Horning, and D. Scott McCrickard. "Willing Buyer, Willing Seller." In GROUP '20: The 2020 ACM International Conference on Supporting Group Work. New York, NY, USA: ACM, 2020. http://dx.doi.org/10.1145/3323994.3369899.
Full textTuson, P. "Willing-seller/willing-buyer model in South Africa." In 20th International Conference and Exhibition on Electricity Distribution (CIRED 2009). IET, 2009. http://dx.doi.org/10.1049/cp.2009.0783.
Full textReports on the topic "Willing buyer-willing seller"
Ashley, Caitlyn, Elizabeth Spencer Berthiaume, Philip Berzin, Rikki Blassingame, Stephanie Bradley Fryer, John Cox, E. Samuel Crecelius, et al. Law and Policy Resource Guide: A Survey of Eminent Domain Law in Texas and the Nation. Edited by Gabriel Eckstein. Texas A&M University School of Law Program in Natural Resources Systems, 2017. http://dx.doi.org/10.37419/eenrs.eminentdomainguide.
Full text